CHAPTER 13 REPAYMENT PLANS
The concept of the consumer repayment plan developed in Birmingham,
Alabama in the 1930s as a means for wage earners to repay their debts through a
court-supervised program. (601) Congress adopted this model nationwide when it enacted Chapter XIII in 1938, and again when it enacted Chapter 13 in 1978. The
districts that provided the initial models for the modern day Chapter 13 maintain their
Chapter 13 high filing rates even today. (602)
The legislative history of the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978 establishes that
Congress sought to promote the use of Chapter 13 in appropriate cases. Many
debtors' representatives, judges, trustees and creditor representatives have spoken in
strong support of Chapter 13. Chapter 13 enables families to get caught up on house
and car loans while it provides a mechanism for repayment of unsecured debt.
Although debtors might choose Chapter 13 over Chapter 7 for a variety of reasons,
curing mortgage and loan defaults is a primary incentive for them to do so.
While the concept of a repayment plan is valuable, the actual implementation
of the Chapter 13 program could be improved on several fronts. The high non-completion rate of Chapter 13 plans is cause for substantial concern. For more than
a decade, two-thirds of all Chapter 13 plans have failed before the debtor completes
payments, and sometimes before unsecured creditors have received anything at all.
While some of the debtors convert to Chapter 7 when plan payments become
infeasible, about half of all debtors who initially file for Chapter 13 are dismissed
with no resolution of their financial problems and no discharge. (603)
Noncompletion may have a number of causes. Some commentators suggest
that debtors frequently encounter repeated financial difficulties or face new crises,
such as the loss of a job or a health emergency. Bankruptcy does not insulate against
subsequent disaster. The same kinds of spotty employment or medical problems that
caused debtors' initial financial problems may reemerge, or new problems might
appear. Subsequent difficulties, coupled with the higher "catch-up" payments on
secured debt, can foil well-intentioned repayment efforts. Others suggest that debtors
propose unrealistic plans that are doomed from the inception, sometimes due in part
to inadequate advice. In an effort to meet the requirements of the Bankruptcy Code
in the treatment of certain creditors or to meet the informal payment requirements of
some judges or trustees, debtors may commit to payment plans that would consume
or exceed every dollar of discretionary income, and make optimistic assumptions
about their income, expected over-time pay, and so on, but do not allow for even
minimal unforeseen expenses. Some simply cannot sustain such payments over time.
Another theory holds that some debtors file for Chapter 13 never intending to
complete their payments; they may cure a default on a secured debt on a home or a
car, then leave bankruptcy when their secured debt payments are current. A related,
but more troubling theory suggests that some number of Chapter 13 debtors have
filed only to get an automatic stay to stop a foreclosure or eviction. When they are
unable to bring the underlying obligation current, they dismiss with an intent to buy
another automatic stay by filing again.
Whatever the causes for the high rate of noncompletion, several consequences
are troubling. First, the many dismissals serve as a reminder that under the current
system, choosing Chapter 13 over Chapter 7 does not guarantee meaningful
repayment to unsecured creditors. For example, in the many jurisdictions that permit
the deferral of unsecured debt payment until the end of the plan, unsecured creditors
may receive a negligible collective payout. For debtors who file only to avoid
foreclosure or eviction, payouts range from nominal to non-existent.
In addition, for the debtors who filed for legitimate purposes but who are too
poor or too disaster-prone to complete their plans, filing and dismissing add to their
financial burdens. When noncompletion leads to dismissal rather than discharge, as
it so often does, debtors exit the system having paid a substantial filing fee and
attorneys' fees but have not discharged any debt. Because interest continues to
accrue and compound on nondischarged debt, the debtor may have an even higher
debt load after making a determined-but ultimately unsuccessful-effort to pay off
debts.
The Commission hearings were peppered with illustrations of the lack of
uniformity in Chapter 13 plan confirmation requirements. Court discretion is an
important and necessary part of any judicial proceeding, and judges must be called
upon to apply legal rules to novel and perplexing sets of facts. However, the
nonuniformity of Chapter 13 plans is more deeply rooted. Chapter 13 practices differ
dramatically from state to state, district to district, and even from judge to judge in
the same district. Debtors in very similar circumstances encounter extremely different
Chapter 13 systems. These variations in the systems determine whether debtors are
eligible for Chapter 13 relief at all and how much they will have to pay for that relief.
Some courts confirm plans paying zero percent to unsecured creditors. Other courts
condition confirmation on payment of high percentages of unsecured debt. A
Chapter 13 debtor who is permitted to devote all disposable income to repaying
nondischargeable debt will emerge from bankruptcy much better off than a debtor
who is required to make pro rata payments on all nonpriority unsecured debt --
dischargeable or nondischargeable -- leaving the debtor with much larger
nondischargeable debts post-bankruptcy. Some observers are not troubled by this
variation. They believe that it reflects appropriate differences in community values.
While some variation may be a healthy part of a legal system, the fundamental
fairness of a system is undermined when the interpretations are so divergent that they
alter the basic requirements of the Chapter 13 bargain.
An overlay of divergent local interpretations onto the already complex
Chapter 13 system creates a situation in which expert legal advice is necessary to
develop, confirm, modify, and complete a Chapter 13 plan. For the majority of
debtors who cannot afford expensive advice, two results may occur. First, some
debtors encounter attorneys who give the low-cost advice to file Chapter 7. Second,
the debtors who end up in the complicated Chapter 13 system without good advice
are unlikely to be able to navigate their way through the process. While there will
never be a substitute for good legal advice, no one benefits when a system for
financially distressed consumers becomes a trap for the unwary. The default rules
should be sufficiently sensible to lead to the proper results without high
administrative costs.
Ironically, the same system that is too complicated for the most needy debtors
can work to the benefit of the few savvy debtors who can exploit some provisions to
extraordinary advantage. With few exceptions, debtors have almost unlimited access
to Chapter 13 even if they have filed numerous cases previously in quick succession.
The bankruptcy court clerk is required to accept the bankruptcy petition of a debtor
who files the appropriate papers and pays the required fee. This filing triggers an
automatic stay. Creditors bear considerable expense when a debtor repeatedly files
Chapter 13 merely to forestall foreclosure, eviction, or other collection action, which
is compounded by the expense of initiating additional proceedings in the bankruptcy
court. The empirical data are insufficient to support an inference of a widespread
trend of improper repeat filings, but there is sufficient regional and anecdotal
documentation that the system permits an individual and/or co-owners or co-tenants
to file repeatedly for Chapter 13 merely for its injunctive powers.
Finally, common sense would dictate that credit reports should identify those
debtors who successfully complete their payment plans, perhaps giving them better
access to future credit than debtors who pay no debts out of future income. However,
this currently is not the case. Not only do credit reports provide incomplete
information regarding a debtor's repayment attempts, but according to many
accounts, Chapter 7 debtors have easier access to credit than Chapter 13 debtors. If
the system is really supposed to encourage debtors to file for Chapter 13, the
incentives currently are perverse.
All of these issues are addressed in the following Recommendations. While
these Recommendations reflect the goal of encouraging debtors to choose Chapter
13 and to complete their plans, it remains to be seen if the rate of successful plan
completion can be improved substantially notwithstanding the fact that completing
a three to five year payment plan can be a difficult undertaking for financially
troubled families. In the meantime, the recommended changes were designed to
increase the fairness and efficiency of the Chapter 13 system for both debtors and
creditors.
1.5.1 Home Mortgages
A Chapter 13 plan could not modify obligations on first mortgages and
refinanced first mortgages, except to the extent currently permitted by
the Bankruptcy Code. Section 1322(b)(2) should be amended to provide
that the rights of a holder of a claim secured only by a junior security
interest in real property that is the debtor's principal residence may not
be modified to reduce the secured claim to less than the appraised value
of the property at the time the security interest was made.
While equality of distribution among creditors is a central tenet of the
bankruptcy system, some creditors' claims get special treatment for policy reasons.
Therefore, although the Bankruptcy Code generally requires secured debts exceeding
the value of collateral to be "stripped down," and thus bifurcated into secured and
unsecured claims, (604) home mortgages are treated differently. Prior to the Supreme
Court's decision in Nobelman v. American Savings Bank, (605) some courts held that the
antimodification policy for home mortgages did not preclude debtors from stripping
down mortgages. (606) The Bankruptcy Code now explicitly provides that certain home
mortgage loans cannot be stripped or modified. (607)
This special treatment for home mortgages is limited. The Bankruptcy Code
does not provide an exception to all holders of liens and interests on homes. For
example, a mortgage can be bifurcated into its secured and unsecured portions if the
house is not the debtor's "primary residence." Likewise, Chapter 13 does not
prohibit modification of a mortgage loan if the loan also is secured by other
collateral. (608) In addition, section 1322(c)(2) authorizes a stripdown of an undersecured residential mortgage if final payment would become due during the
course of the Chapter 13 plan. (609) Moreover, a number of courts have held that a mortgage can be modified if it is wholly unsecured. (610) None of the Commission's Recommendations would alter any of these rules.
Notwithstanding these "exceptions to the exception," the special protection
for mortgage lenders in the Bankruptcy Code is relatively consistent with pervasive
federal policies promoting home ownership. (611) Protection against modification and
stripdown was designed to insulate home mortgage lenders to preserve families'
access to home purchase financing. By eliminating the additional hurdles to
mortgagees' efforts to collect the full amount of their debts from homeowners, the
theory goes, mortgage lenders will be willing to take on higher risk borrowers and
keep mortgage rates lower.
Home mortgages also provide a valuable source of financing for other
purposes. Mortgage loans have become an increasingly popular method to finance
important family life events, such as sending a child to college. (612) In many cases, this
method of financing has advantages to the borrower. Tax advantages provide
incentives to finance through home equity loans. (613) Furthermore, traditional lenders
generally grant these loans and lines of credit at competitive interest rates that are
substantially lower than unsecured credit. These advantages encourage families to
take the risk associated with pledging one's home to secure a loan.
Families appear to be accepting these incentives to borrow against their
homes. As access to home equity loans grows, consumers are increasing their debt
loads by borrowing against their homes. (614) Homes are mortgaged more than ever, with the Federal Reserve reporting a loan-to-value ratio of about 64% in 1996. (615)
Homeowners in bankruptcy have borrowed against their homes in even larger
proportions than other Americans. (616) All signs indicate that the access will continue to increase. Home equity loans now can be obtained through automated loan
machines in supermarkets and malls, (617) and changes in lending regulations now permit pre-approved solicitations and advertisements of second mortgages. (618)
Many of these families obtain home equity loans from lenders that use less
conservative lending practices. These more aggressive lenders tend to offer interest
rates and terms that are not appreciably better than unsecured credit and often double
the conventional first mortgage loan rate. (619) Factoring in points, closing costs, and prepayment penalties, the effective interest rate may climb even higher. This leads
some to question whether too much home equity financing "endanger[s] the financial
health" of America's families. (620)
Among these high interest home equity loans, some mortgages are partly
unsecured as of the day the loan is made; the lender makes a larger loan or extends
more credit than the property's worth. (621) Under this relatively new phenomenon, some lenders encourage debtors to borrow over 100%-and sometimes up to 125%-of
the value of their homes at higher-than-market interest rates. (622) Unlike mortgages that are fully secured until the market declines, these junior mortgages are taken on a
partially unsecured basis and should be treated accordingly in the bankruptcy process.
These high leverage loans are the subject of the Commission's
Recommendation. (623) The Commission proposes that a junior mortgage lender should be treated as a fully secured creditor only to the extent it was secured when
it made the loan. The only effect of the Proposal is to treat the unsecured portion of
the loan like other unsecured debt. The remainder of the loan would enjoy the
antimodification protection to the extent that current law provides. Some
lenders also make undersecured first mortgage loans, but the Commission's
Recommendation does not include first mortgage loans. This Recommendation is
similar in intent, although not identical in detail, to provisions in H.R. 6020 and
S.1985, two bills that led up to the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1994. (624)
This Recommendation is also consistent with underlying federal policies
promoting home ownership. High leverage loans put homeownership at risk. If
creditors making loans in excess of the home's value can demand full repayment or
can force a foreclosure, some borrowers will lose their homes. Debtors with second
and third mortgages that exceed the value of their homes are less likely to confirm
a Chapter 13 plan, thereby yielding no payments to any other creditors.
The home mortgage market should not be affected adversely by this
Recommendation. Underwriting standards of traditional mortgage lenders preclude
high loan-to-value mortgages, particularly those in which the loan exceeds the value
of the collateral. They use strict underwriting standards, and the maximum combined
home loan to value ratio for bank mortgages at loan origination generally falls around
75%. The Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac) does not
purchase high loan-to-value home equity lines of credit. Second mortgage loans
constituted less than one percent of the holdings of the Federal National Mortgage
Association (Fannie Mae) and less than one half of one percent of Freddie Mac's
holdings of total single family mortgages in 1993, and the percentage has not
changed appreciably since then. (625) Like a significant segment of the home equity loans, (626) high leverage mortgages are packaged into securities but are sold in a
separate securities market. Any risk associated with these mortgages is therefore
diffused through securitization.
This Proposal takes a very modest step that should not have any appreciable
effect on mortgage pricing. Empirical evidence does not support the allegation that
treating home mortgage loans more like other secured debts would affect mortgage
pricing. For example, in predicting the effect of different collection laws on
mortgage rates, empirical studies of state mortgagor protection statutes have
demonstrated that mortgage interest rates are relatively insensitive to the existence
of mortgagor protection laws. (627)
This Proposal would limit the preference that high leverage mortgagees
receive under current law. Permitting modification of partially secured junior
mortgages comports with the continuing effort to treat like creditors more alike. (628)
However, it does not go all the way to providing equal treatment to similarly situated
creditors. Treatment keyed to the value of the property at the time of the loan is not
consistent with the general approach to value property during the bankruptcy
proceeding. In other instances in bankruptcy, a creditor's secured status is calculated
during the course of the bankruptcy. Using loan valuation may intensify the
incentive for lenders to over-appraise collateral at the inception of the loan, which
might undercut the intent of the Recommendation and create other problems outside
of bankruptcy. In addition, families in Chapter 13 may not be able to afford to
contest that appraisal, which means that lenders might prevail in most cases
regardless of the merits of the appraisal. However, the Proposal takes a first step
toward treating all loans in accordance with economic reality. The valuation
approach used here is born of compromise, not principle.
1.5.2 Valuation
A creditor's secured claim in personal property should be determined by
the property's wholesale price.
A creditor's secured claim in real property should be determined by the
property's fair market value, minus hypothetical costs of sale.
The need for statutory guidance on the valuation of collateral was a consistent
theme throughout the Commission's hearings. On this basis, early versions of the
Commission's consumer bankruptcy work contained a recommendation for a
compromise valuation standard that would not entail a fact-intensive inquiry or
require extensive litigation. Once it became clear that the Supreme Court would
speak directly to the issue of valuation in Associates Commercial Corp. v. Rash, the
Commission deferred further consideration of the precise standard to be
recommended. In June of 1997, the Supreme Court issued a ruling in which it
concluded that the relevant statutory provision, as it currently is written, requires a
fact-intensive analysis. (629) Having the benefit of the Court's interpretation, the
Commission decided to revisit the underlying question of whether a statutory
recommendation was in order to render this fact intensive analysis unnecessary. At
the August 1997 meeting, the Commission discussed the Rash decision and
concluded that a statutory amendment would be beneficial and directed that materials
be prepared accordingly, which ultimately resulted in this Recommendation.
Chapter 13 permits a debtor to confirm a repayment plan over the objection
of a secured creditor if the debtor pays the secured creditor the present value of its
allowed secured claim, which is determined by the value of the collateral. (630) The
appropriate method to assess "value" is not clearly defined by the Bankruptcy Code
and instead is left to case-by-case determination. Section 506(a), which is supposed
to provide guidance, states as follows:
An allowed claim of a creditor secured by a lien on property in which
the estate has an interest, or that is subject to setoff under section 553
of this title, is a secured claim to the extent of the value of such
creditor's interest in the estate's interest in such property, or to the
extent of the amount subject to setoff, as the case may be, and is an
unsecured claim to the extent that the value of such creditor's interest
or the amount so subject to setoff is less than the amount of such
allowed claim. Such value shall be determined in light of the purpose
of the valuation and of the proposed disposition or use of such
property, and in conjunction with any hearing on such disposition or
use or on a plan affecting such creditor's interest.
Due to the flexibility inherent in this provision, the extent of the allowed secured
claim may vary depending on the type of bankruptcy case, the type of property, and
the proposed disposition of the collateral. (631) Even in low-dollar-amount cases, therefore, there is no bright-line rule to give parties cheap and expedient answers to
valuation questions. With the method to make this determination left completely
undefined, courts have applied disparate methods to similar circumstances, yielding
results ranging from the highest (i.e., retail) to the lowest (i.e., forced sale) possible
valuations, with many options in between, including replacement cost, wholesale,
and "midpoint" (the average of net resale proceeds and retail, a compromise method
derived from Chapter 13 trustees). (632) Circuit courts of appeals have differed over the proper standard for determining the allowed secured claim. (633) The announced standards have not always been clear, evidenced by the fact that judges reach conflicting interpretations of prior court decisions addressing valuation standards. (634)
To address a split in the circuits, the United States Supreme Court released
a much-awaited decision on this issue, Associates Commercial Corp. v. Rash. (635)
Rash was a Chapter 13 case involving a tractor truck used by the debtor in his freight
hauling business. In an en banc opinion reversing the initial appellate ruling that
retail value determined the allowed secured claim, the United States Court of
Appeals for the Fifth Circuit held that the valuation of a secured creditor's interest
under section 506(a) "should start with what the creditor could realize if it
repossessed and sold the collateral pursuant to its security agreement, taking into
account the purpose of the valuation and the proposed distribution or use of the
collateral."(636) The court therefore determined that the bankruptcy court did not err when it valued the truck at wholesale; this price reflected the secured creditor's
hypothetical yield had it repossessed and sold the truck.
The Supreme Court reversed and remanded the Fifth Circuit's en banc
decision. The Supreme Court looked to the second sentence of that section 506(a),
which requires a court to consider the proposed disposition or use of the property.
The proper valuation standard if the collateral remained with the debtor, said the
Supreme Court with only one dissenter, was replacement value less certain costs.
Unlike other interpretations of the term "replacement value" that sometimes equate
it with retail value, the Supreme Court's definition clearly requires deductions for
certain costs, such as warranties, inventory costs, storage, and reconditioning. This
would entail a fact-intensive analysis, with the actual method of determination to be
left to individual judges.
The Supreme Court's adoption of a replacement-value-less-certain-costs
standard reflected a deliberate policy choice. In footnote five, the Court stated that
it sought to clarify the law. It "reject[ed] a ruleless approach allowing use of
different valuation standards based on the facts and circumstances of individual
cases." Notwithstanding the announced intent of this standard, the application of the
standard is again fraught with ambiguity. In footnote six, the Supreme Court
commented that the fact that the replacement value standard "governs in cramdown
cases leaves to bankruptcy courts, as triers of fact, identification of the best way of
ascertaining replacement value on the basis of the evidence presented. Whether
replacement value is the equivalent of retail value, wholesale value, or some other
value will depend on the type of property." The Supreme Court went on to describe
the types of expenses that should be deducted to reach replacement value, each of
which requires an independent determination. The variations based on the types of
property and the expenses to be deducted make clear that a fact-intensive analysis
and multiple valuations would be inevitable.
While the court uses the term "replacement value" that is sometimes
associated with retail, the explanation of its calculation indicates a different, more
complex valuation. Because the Supreme Court's ruling was based on the
interpretation of section 506(a), rather than on a more comprehensive policy
judgment about what the appropriate valuation standard should be, the Commission
recommends that Congress provide more guidance in this area to ensure that similar
cases would be treated more equally and to reduce unnecessary litigation and
transaction costs. The Commission's Recommendation aims at a valuation based on
fewer factors to be evaluated using a standard provable with relatively more ease.
Significance of Establishing a Standard to Determine the Allowed Secured
Claim and the Problems with the "Replacement Value Less Certain Costs" Standard.
Although the Supreme Court ruled in the context of a Chapter 13 cramdown, the
standard for valuing the allowed secured claim has significant implications in all
cases. (637) Issues involving the valuation of property arise in almost every bankruptcy
case, consumer or business. (638) Valuation is central to adequate protection contests
and to the plan confirmation process, and thus greatly affects negotiations in complex
business reorganization cases. (639) Although section 506(a) establishes that valuation
is to be done on a case-by-case basis, the Supreme Court's interpretation of section
506(a) calls into question the valuation standards heretofore used in all of these
contexts. (640)
As a consequence of the approach taken by the Supreme Court majority,
commentators fear that the Rash decision will exacerbate litigation on valuation
issues. There are numerous practical difficulties of determining replacement value, (641)
particularly under the open-ended approach set forth in footnote six of the decision. (642)
The inquiry entails many factual determinations regarding the amounts that must be
deducted from the retail price. In many cases, the secured claim will be determined
after a protracted "battle of the experts,"(643) which can dissipate assets that otherwise
would be available for distribution to other creditors.
A clearer standard that does not change from one factual setting to another
is warranted to provide certainty and consistency for all valuation determinations.
Simplicity is a prerequisite to any standard to be considered for adoption. A
relatively simple standard reduces litigation costs while it increases the predictability
of outcomes, permitting parties to settle their differences without always turning to
the courts. A simple standard also promotes consistency in application among
different judges and different districts, increasing the likelihood that similar cases
will be analyzed using similar legal principles.
This Proposal recommends that the same baseline standards be employed for
all valuation purposes. While the language of section 506(a) has been interpreted to
permit-and perhaps mandate-different standards depending on the context of the
valuation, it is not entirely clear why the same piece of property should be valued by
various standards in multiple proceedings depending on the nature of each
proceeding. Although valuation arises in a variety of legal contexts, the factual
circumstances warranting valuation are limited: an estimate of valuation is required
when the debtor plans to retain the property. (644) There has been little explanation for why one valuation standard should be used for adequate protection and another for
plan confirmation, one for determining the value of non-exempt property and another
for the redemption of exempt property. Nor has there been an adequate argument
made for why Chapter 13 valuations should be any different than valuations in
Chapter 11 or any other chapter. (645) Without a clearly articulated principle to justify the propriety of various valuation standards in different procedural contexts,
confusion is compounded with no offsetting gain.
The variety of applications of valuation standards demonstrate that no
particular method can be deemed "pro-debtor" or "pro-creditor." Depending on the
circumstances, parties have different stakes in favoring a high or low valuation. For
example, people might assume that the full "replacement value" standard is favorable
to creditors. However, if the replacement value standard is used in automatic stay
hearings, a court is more likely to find that the debtor has equity in the collateral and
thus not lift the stay to permit the creditor to proceed with its rights against the
property. Likewise, a creditor is less likely to be entitled to adequate protection
payments using a high replacement value standard even though the creditor may not
be fully protected in the event of a foreclosure if the reorganization effort fails. (646) In
such circumstances, high valuation can leave a secured creditor unprotected.
Depending on the context, the valuation standard can yield quite different
consequences.
In addition, no method of valuation is uniformly favorable to all creditors; the
method of valuation that benefits a secured creditor in a particular situation is
correspondingly less beneficial to unsecured creditors. (647) This can be seen readily
in the present Chapter 13 system, in which every dollar of "disposable income" must
be made available to unsecured creditors. The smaller the secured claim of a lender,
including interest payments, the larger the pro rata return to the unsecured
creditors. (648) All parties have an important stake in the outcome of a valuation dispute.
Wholesale Price as a Compromise Bright-Line Standard. Among the
spectrum of various options for valuation, from retail (highest value) to forced sale
(lowest value), the Commission recommends that a price in the middle-wholesale
price-be used to determine the allowed secured claim for personal property under
section 506(a). This approach is supported by policy considerations and offers
several advantages.
To start, many items of personal property have a readily identifiable
wholesale price. Motor vehicles, an item of property frequently listed in consumer
bankruptcies, will be one of the easiest to determine. Rather than working through
"replacement value" and then calculating deductions for items such as such as
warranties, inventory costs, advertising, storage, and reconditioning, wholesale value
is readily ascertainable. (649) The National Automobile Dealers Association ("NADA") blue book is available throughout the country. (650) Wholesale prices for other types of
personal property in the consumer context, such as musical instruments, can be
ascertained with relative ease. Wholesale price satisfies the first fundamental
requirement for a bright-line rule-that it be workable-and thus helps to avoid
transaction costs in bankruptcy. (651)
Wholesale value can be calculated even when an item does not have a readily
identifiable wholesale market by reference to a retail market for similar goods.
Because the term "wholesale" triggers a distinction between old and new goods, it
helps identify the proper market. The proper market is one that deals in goods of the
kind to be valued-in their current state. In a consumer context, such property will
nearly always be used, although in a business context, new or used property might
be the correct valuation. For some consumer goods, a sale in the "want ads" or at
garage sales or flea markets may be the only market for certain types of used goods.
Since such markets are, by definition, not "retail" (and typically are not priced to
include warranties and sales commissions), this is "wholesale." No further
calculation is needed. By making wholesale valuation the standard, in cases where
no wholesale market exists, it would be possible to construct the price through a
mechanism similar to that recommended in Rash, but with an easier application.
Following the Supreme Court's instructions in footnote six, a court likely would start
with retail and subtract most costs that comprise the difference between the retail and
wholesale prices. (652)
In addition, "compromise" is an element that many parties have sought in a
valuation standard. (653) Wholesale price provides a compromise between the lower valuations, such as resale price and foreclosure price, and the higher retail value. (654)
Wholesale price can be viewed as a midpoint. However, because forced sales often
yield so little, wholesale is often much closer to retail than to foreclosure. (655)
Another compromise that has been suggested is specifically denominated a
"midpoint" valuation, a standard embraced by the Seventh Circuit Court of Appeals
in In re Hoskins prior to the Rash decision. (656) In Hoskins, the bankruptcy court had
approved a valuation of the collateral that literally was the average of the highest and
lowest values. Because the Chapter 13 trustee did not appeal the midpoint value on
behalf of the unsecured creditors, foreclosure or wholesale values were not options
before the Seventh Circuit. The midpoint valuation has the benefit of ensuring that
neither the secured creditors nor the unsecured creditors reap a benefit at the
complete expense of the each other. It avoids windfalls and neutralizes the strategic
power that either set of creditors would enjoy under the alternative rules. (657) For this
reason, some districts have adopted the midpoint valuation by local rule. (658)
A wholesale valuation accomplishes much of the same goals because it
permits the parties to share in the benefit of the reorganization. A compromise
approach is consistent with the notion that the chosen valuation standard should not
create perverse incentives to use bankruptcy strategically. If creditors can count on
property valuations well in excess of the creditors' state law entitlements, then they
have an incentive to push for bankruptcy rather than out-of-court workouts. At the
same time, if property valuations in bankruptcy will be far below what the debtor
could yield by selling the property, the debtor can use bankruptcy to extract value
from creditors in ways that are not consistent with bankruptcy principles. A clear
standard pegged at a compromise point is most likely to keep strategic maneuvering
by either party to a minimum.
While "wholesale" and "midpoint" might be similar to each other in many
cases, using "wholesale" valuation has clear advantages. Unlike the "midpoint"
compromise which requires two separate valuations, wholesale valuation requires the
identification of only one price. Certainty increases as administrative costs decrease
with a wholesale valuation.
An important policy consideration underlies adoption of a wholesale
valuation. Quite significantly, adoption of a wholesale valuation ensures that a
creditor's secured claim will cover at least what the creditor would have received
under state law. This standard properly defines property rights in the absence of an
overriding bankruptcy policy. (659) The Uniform Commercial Code entitles a secured
creditor to seize and sell the collateral in a commercially reasonable fashion, such as
an auction. (660) If the creditor is entitled to a higher replacement cost or retail, the
creditor has a larger entitlement than if the debtor surrendered the property, without
having to incur the expenses necessary to fetch a retail price. Choosing wholesale
protects secured creditors at least for the resale price, which some argue is the most
accurate reflection of state law entitlements. (661) Of course, in a limited-asset system
such as bankruptcy, what is guaranteed to any one creditor is taken from other
parties. Wholesale valuation, because it is typically higher than foreclosure or
repossession valuation, potentially provides secured creditors with more than they
would receive under non-bankruptcy law. By looking to wholesale price, a secured
creditor should be protected at least for "the equivalent of recourse to the
collateral,"(662) when the creditor gets, in effect, its best price.
The wholesale standard also is fair to debtors. A debtor who retains collateral
will have to pay more than liquidation value on the allowed secured claim, but the
debtor has the opportunity to keep the property, an option not available to the debtor
outside bankruptcy. Thus, the debtor also receives a benefit it would not have
received if the property had been repossessed under state law.
No valuation standard can be wholly satisfactory to all parties. The zero-sum
game of many bankruptcy decisions necessarily reveals itself somewhere. Using
wholesale valuation, the unsecured creditors may be the losers as compared to what
they could have received if foreclosure value was adopted. This is particularly true
under the current "disposable income" requirement that determines unsecured
creditor distributions in Chapter 13 based in part on what is left over after paying
secured creditors. While the Commission's Recommendation to replace the Chapter
13 disposable income requirement with a flat percentage would de-link valuation
from unsecured creditor returns to a certain extent, it still is clear that the wholesale
standard is less advantageous to unsecured creditors than a foreclosure sale standard.
At the same time, wholesale is less likely to cut unsecured creditors out completely
than the higher retail standard.
However, the wholesale standard should promote overall economic
efficiency. The purpose of collateral is to serve as a source of payment for a loan in
the event that the borrower defaults. Providing at least the value that a creditor could
realize following repossession and resale of that particular collateral reflects that
purpose. If a high valuation relative to the actual value precludes the confirmation
of a feasible plan, a debtor will forfeit the collateral to a creditor that will receive
only the much lower foreclosure price upon repossession and foreclosure. Thus, a
higher valuation standard would force the transfer of property to a party that would
yield a lower return for it. Wholesale valuation may be more economically efficient
because the debtor will be able to keep the property in those cases where the debtor
values it most. (663)
When determining how to calculate the allowed secured claim, it also is
important to recognize the goal of the valuation exercise: an accurate valuation of the
asset to capture the present value of the asset's future cash flows. Wholesale price
is a much better approximation of the collateral's actual value because retail price
reflects an extra component of a retailer's value-adding attributes that are not relevant
or appropriate in this context, especially when the secured creditor is not a retailer
itself. (664) Even when the secured creditor is a retailer, there are very real expenses that
the creditor must expend to resell an item for a retail price. The Supreme Court
seemed to recognize this underlying economic reality in footnote six of its decision
in Rash, and the Commission's Recommendation reflects this reality as well.
Fair Market Value Minus Hypothetical Costs of Sale. In valuing real
property, fair market value minus hypothetical costs of sale provides a parallel
standard. (665) A number of circuit courts of appeals have adopted the fair market value standard for assessing the allowed secured claim on real property. (666) The proposed approach diverges from those court decisions in that they have not deducted hypothetical costs of sale. Refusing to deduct hypothetical costs generally has been
justified by the same arguments employed to support retail valuation of personal
property: because these courts focus on the debtors' intended use of the property,
e.g., continued possession, they have found that it would be unreasonable to deduct
costs when no sale is intended. Other courts sharply disagree with this premise; they
instead base their inquiries on the creditor's interest in the property and note that a
secured creditor could never realize fair market value without incurring disposition
costs, and thus these must be factored into the valuation. (667)
The Recommendation proposes deducting sales costs from the fair market
price for several reasons. A fair market value standard properly sets the allowed
secured claim at an amount that represents what a willing and fully informed buyer
would pay under fair market conditions. It is the best approximation of the
property's market value and reflects that there is less difference for real property
between the price that a debtor and the price another party could obtain for the
property outside the context of a foreclosure sale. Typically, there is no wholesale
market for real estate. A wholesale approach to real estate, therefore, is "retail" less
expenses, as Rash generally establishes.
Fair market value less costs also is a good compromise. Fair market value
less costs of sale is higher than a foreclosure or forced sale price, but only slightly
less than a non-adjusted fair market price, assuming that a foreclosure sale price often
is lower than fair market value. (668) To that extent it provides a reasonably parallel
approach to the wholesale standard, again offering a "compromise" valuation method
that is easier to administer than another midpoint standard that would require two
valuations.
Deducting costs of sale also better reflects a secured creditor's state law
entitlement, which must be considered in this type of analysis. (669) If the secured
creditor foreclosed and exercised its state law remedies, its return would be far less
than fair market value without cost adjustments.
In addition, section 506(c), which permits costs of sale to be surcharged
against a secured creditor's collateral, supports the notion that costs of sale can
lower the return and, thus, the ultimate value to a secured creditor. (670) If the price received does not cover the costs of sale plus the full amount of the loan, the secured
creditor's recovery is reduced, and the secured creditor's claim is bifurcated into its
secured and unsecured portions. On the other hand, if the price received for the
property is sufficient to cover both the costs of sale and the secured claim, then the
secured creditor is protected in full. The Recommendation puts the secured creditor
whose collateral is retained in the same position as the secured creditor whose
collateral is sold.
A balance between secured and unsecured creditors is more fairly established
when the allowed amount of creditor's secured claim is adjusted for the costs it did
not have to incur to be protected for the fair market price. Again, this permits all
parties to participate and share in the benefits of the reorganization. However, the
parties who again may be shortchanged by a fair market valuation are the unsecured
creditors, who more likely would yield a greater return with a foreclosure sale
valuation standard.
Competing Considerations. Some would criticize the wholesale and fair
market less cost standards as being too high. These standards, it has been argued,
provide a windfall to secured creditors that bargained for and would receive only
foreclosure value outside bankruptcy, where they also would have to bear the costs
and burdens attendant to those collection activities. The high valuation used here is
contrary to a policy of encouraging debtors to file for Chapter 13 and makes it more
difficult for them to confirm plans and to complete their repayment obligations. To
the extent that distributions to unsecured creditors depend on valuation of collateral,
the interests of unsecured creditors are harmed by these higher valuation standards.
Perhaps reflecting the compromise nature of this approach, the recommended
valuation standard also has been criticized for being too low. Some argue that
wholesale valuation permits the debtor to obtain a windfall in the event that the
debtor resold the property for retail price. (671) Of course, this argument has little
applicability in the context of most consumer cases or in any case in which the debtor
is not in the business of selling that particular type of collateral. The debtor is ill-equipped to take the steps that add the requisite value that would be necessary to
fetch a retail price, such as providing a warranty, reconditioning the property,
offering credit terms, or being well located in a shopping area. (672) More significantly,
this circumstance is economically unlikely in a competitive market, according to
some scholars and economists: "[i]f such opportunities did exist, we would expect
to see persons enter the market to take advantage of them. These new market
entrants would bid up the wholesale price until it eventually equaled the retail
price."(673) The reason a difference exists between wholesale and retail, they explain, is that value is added at the retail level.
Some have argued that a different policy issue should be reflected in the
valuation standard. They argue that property valuation should be sufficiently high
to offset the risk of loss to the creditor. According to this argument, valuation should
be high because it may be inaccurate or because the value may decline. However,
risk can be addressed through other means. Compensation for risk of loss can be
accomplished in ways such as adjustment of the amortization rate, adjustment of the
interest rate, calculation of adequate protection payments, or changes in other terms
of the agreement. By using these devices, the question of risk is squarely presented,
not buried in a broad rule of valuation. The Bankruptcy Code's current approach is
more accurate because it is based on actual risk, not a universally-presumed risk
incorporated into a valuation standard applicable to all debtors and all situations.
1.5.3 Payments on secured debts that are subject to modification should be
spread over the life of the plan, according to fixed criteria for interest
rates.
Interest Rate
Closely related to the question of valuation is the issue of interest rates to be
paid on secured claims, an issue not resolved in Rash. A secured creditor is entitled
to the present value of its allowed secured claim, but section 1325(a)(5)(B)(ii) does
not specify what interest rate will give a creditor "present value." During the
legislative process leading to the Bankruptcy Amendments and Federal Judgeship
Act of 1984, Congress specifically considered, but rejected, an amendment that
would have required that interest be paid at the contract rate. (674) The absence of statutory authority has led courts to employ different methods to determine the
appropriate rate of interest. Some districts have adopted local rules to deal with
applicable interest rates payable in bankruptcy. This is a subject on which there is
circuit court authority, but the circuits have settled on different legal rules. In short,
the variety of opinions and authorities using different interest rates to determine
"present value" has multiplied many times since the adoption of the 1978 Code.
Some courts endorse the use of a market rate of interest and have found that
the nondefault contract rate presumptively is the market rate absent evidence to the
contrary. (675) According to this view, the objective of section 1325(a)(5)(B)(ii) is to
put the creditor in the same economic position as if it received the value of its
allowed claim immediately. Sometimes called the "forced loan" rule, this approach
bases the section 1325(a)(5)(B)(ii) interest rate what the creditor charges for loans of
similar character, amount, and duration to debtors in the same geographic region. (676)
Because Chapter 13 cases involve small dollar amounts that could be consumed in
litigation expenses if the rules are too complicated, courts taking this approach may
presume that the contract rate is the market rate. (677)
Other courts use a different market rate, the "cost of funds" to the creditor.
Thus, the rate that should be paid is what the creditor pays to borrow funds.
According to this view, assuming that the creditor would borrow the money
representing the value of its allowed claim is the best way to put a creditor in the
same economic position as if the debtor surrendered the collateral immediately. The
creditor then could make new loans to consumers at prevailing rates in the
commercial market. (678) The proponents of the approach believe that the forced loan
rate used by other courts contains an element of profit that should not be included in
the cramdown interest rate, lest the creditor receive more than the present value of
its allowed claim. (679) They argue that courts should not award profit, administration
costs, risk, industry transactional costs, costs of collection, and the other extra
elements that go into a contract interest rate. (680)
A third method employs the cost of funds approach but also attempts to
reconcile the fact that it provides nonuniform treatment to Chapter 13 debtors. This
consideration led the Second Circuit to hold that the market rate of interest under
section 1325(a)(5)(B)(ii) should be fixed at the prevailing rate of a United States
Treasury instrument with a maturity equivalent to the repayment schedule under the
debtor's reorganization plan. (681) Because the rate on a treasury bond is virtually
risk-free, the court also found that the cramdown interest rate should include a
premium to reflect the risk that the creditor bears in receiving deferred payments
under the reorganization plan. (682) The Second Circuit held that a risk premium should
be added to the prevailing interest rate, suggesting that a premium of 1-3% would be
appropriate, but left the ultimate determination to the discretion of the bankruptcy
judge.
Most agree that the Chapter 13 system should supply a uniform rule. The
uncertainty regarding the proper interest rate has two negative consequences. First,
debtors appearing before one judge may be required to pay a significantly lower rate
of interest than debtors appearing before other judges even when both the debts and
the risks are virtually identical. Aside from yielding different returns to secured
creditors, this section yields diverse distributions to similarly situated unsecured
creditors as well, for in the current Chapter 13 system, the amount of money allocated
to interest payments on secured debt is deducted directly from the amount that
otherwise would be available for distribution to unsecured creditors. The uncertainty
over interest rates also causes unnecessary litigation when money is scarce, further
reducing both the debtor's ability to confirm a plan and the creditors' ultimate
recovery. In many cases, the costs of litigation over interest rates would more than
exceed the amount at stake. Most people therefore agree that the Code should clarify
the proper Chapter 13 plan interest rate.
The Commission recommends that the rate of interest should be determined
using a nationally recognized rate to promote the equal treatment of similarly situated
debtors and creditors. The Commission does not recommend a particular rate. Its
previous discussions have referred to the six-month treasury bills rate as a starting
point, with additional points added thereto for a risk premium.
With respect to the cure of a default on any debt pursuant to a plan, including
mortgage debt, interest under section 1322(e) would run at the nondefault contract
rate. Section 1322(e) was added to the Code by the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1994
to overrule the result reached by the Supreme Court in Rake v. Wade. (683) Rake had
held that a Chapter 13 debtor must pay interest on a mortgage arrearage as a condition
of cure and reinstatement, even if the mortgage contract had not so required. Because
the debtor effectively would have to pay interest on interest, it provided a windfall
to secured creditors that they would not have received if the debtor had not filed for
bankruptcy. Rake thus worked to the detriment of unsecured creditors by
reducing the distribution available to them. Section 1322(e) requires that the
amount necessary to cure a default must be determined in accordance with the
underlying agreement and applicable nonbankruptcy law. This rule was intended to
put the debtor in the same position as if the default had never occurred. (684)
Competing Considerations. A rule providing for interest at the nondefault
contract rate also would be easy to apply. This rate would bind the debtors to their original
bargains to the extent possible. Moreover, it arguably represents a fair proxy for
general market rates of interest applicable to the collateral at issue. (685) Such an
interest rate arguably includes a calculation for profit, potentially giving the creditor
more than it would have received had the property been foreclosed. The contract
rate also does not provide the same consistency that could be obtained through the
use of a uniform rate. A Chapter 13 payment plan involves different and broader
considerations than were contemplated in the bilateral contract between the debtor
and one creditor. Distributions to a secured creditor based on interest payments
reduce the resources available to pay unsecured creditors, who typically do not
receive full payment of the underlying debt and who almost never receive any interest
payments.
Secured Debt Payments Spread Over Life of Plan
Under the current system, payments to secured creditors frequently are made
at the beginning of the plan. This provides a quicker cure for defaults, but it has
corollary consequences. It delays payments to unsecured creditors for several years.
Furthermore, because a debtor can cure an arrearage on a secured loan and dismiss
the case, unsecured creditors may never get paid at all. Included among the
unsecured creditors who do not receive a pro rata distribution are the secured
creditors whose liens were stripped to the value of the collateral.
The Commission recommends that payments to secured creditors be spread
over the life of the plan concurrently with pro rata distributions to unsecured
creditors, also spread over the life of the plan. Because debtors would not be able to front load
their cure payments and dismiss the plan, this method would increase the likelihood of a
higher number of distributions to unsecured creditors and would enhance the probability
that debtors will stay in their plans for the full term.
This approach is not without its risks. Stretching out payments and requiring
concurrent secured and unsecured payments may increase the risk of plan failure and
heighten the consequences of failure to the debtor, such as the loss of a car. It is
possible that other types of changes, such as restrictions on entitlements in serial
cases, are more suitable methods to address alleged misuse of Chapter 13 without
increasing the likelihood of failure for other debtors.
At the same time, some might argue that this procedure might not protect
creditors sufficiently, especially if the debtor had only a few more payments when
filing for bankruptcy. A too-low uniform interest rate may not protect creditors'
interests adequately if payments are extended through the full plan term.
1.5.4 Unsecured Debt
Payments on unsecured debt should be determined by guidelines based
on a graduated percentage of the debtor's income, subject to upward
adjustment to meet the section 1325(a)(4) requirement that creditors
receive at least the present value of whatever they would have received
in a Chapter 7. The trustee or an unsecured creditor should be
authorized to file an objection to any plan that deviated from the
guidelines, and a court would determine whether the deviation was
appropriate in light of all the circumstances.
Under current law, payments to unsecured creditors are generally determined
by the "disposable income requirement." Section 1325 of the Bankruptcy Code
provides that a court can confirm a Chapter 13 plan over the objection of the trustee
or a creditor if the debtor commits three years' worth of "disposable income" to
paying unsecured creditors under the plan. (686) This concept was introduced into the
Chapter 13 system by the Consumer Credit Amendments in 1984. (687)
The disposable income approach has facial appeal to both creditors and
debtors, albeit for different reasons. Being entitled to all disposable income connotes
to unsecured creditors that they will receive every extra penny of income for several
years, creating the inference that Chapter 13 is a successful repayment mechanism.
For debtors, the fact that the unsecured debt payment is keyed to disposable income
signifies that they will not be shut out of Chapter 13--even if they are unable to make
substantial payment--as long as they agree to contribute whatever income they have
left after paying all of their other expenses. Neither of these connotations of the
disposable income has borne out fully in reality. While the disposable income
approach enjoys support across various segments of the bankruptcy community, it
has some significant shortcomings in practice that should be brought to light.
Calculating the "disposable" portion of the debtor's income starts with the
inherently subjective scrutiny of the expenses that the debtor insists are necessary.
To the extent that debtors completely encumber their income with expenses that are
considered "reasonably necessary," they have no disposable income at all.
Consequently, if their plans are confirmed, their unsecured creditors receive nothing.
Conversely, if a court does not share a debtor's view of reasonable expenses and
recalculates the debtor's disposable income to be a higher amount, the plan will not
be confirmed unless the debtor agrees to make other sacrifices to make that amount
available.
Courts take different approaches to overseeing satisfaction of the disposable
income requirement. Some courts or trustees conduct only a limited review of
debtors' budget and scrutinize only luxury items while other courts take on the role
of an "itemized examiner."(688) Under any approach, however, it is all too clear that
after thirteen years' experience with the disposable income requirement, courts seem
no closer to sharing a collective view of what constitutes "reasonably necessary
expenses" than they were at the inception. Some courts believe that private schools
are necessary, while others do not. (689) Orthodontia, piano lessons, college tuition, (690)
home repairs, dry cleaning, newspapers, (691) tithing, (692) utility payments, and food
allocations are just a few of the expenses that are scrutinized in this context.
Personal views of what is and what is not necessary for a family inescapably factor
into the equation. The amount that debtors must pay to their unsecured creditors
will differ from courtroom to courtroom not because of different circumstances, but
because of divergent views on the expenses perceived to be reasonably necessary. (693)
Because the inquiry is so fact-specific and non-legal, published opinions have little
precedential value. Any party can threaten to litigate, knowing that there is some
case law to support any position. The confusion over standards increases the leverage
of any party with the resources and the stamina to fight about disposable income.
The wide variability in Chapter 13 practices make it difficult for unsecured
creditors to monitor cases for proposed debt repayments. With only pro rata
distribution as a reward, challenging a proposed repayment plan is not a sound
financial strategy when the courts have no predictable rules about the amount they
will require the debtor to pay. (694)
The "disposable income" concept also is at odds with other goals of the
Chapter 13 system. Difficulties in budgeting and managing finances were partly
responsible for many debtors' ultimate resort to the bankruptcy system. However,
the basis of the disposable income concept is the debtor's budget. Chapter 13
rewards debtors who over-encumber their budgets with "reasonably necessary"
expenses by requiring them to pay less to their unsecured creditors. A debtor who
purchases a big car and some new furniture on credit and moves to a larger apartment
shortly before bankruptcy may be obligated to pay less to the unsecured creditors
than a debtor with the same income with an old car and old furniture and a smaller
apartment. In either case, the debtor cannot keep the income. The question
economically is whether the debtors' income will be channeled to unsecured debt or
whether the debtor can use the income in ways that will qualify as "reasonably
necessary expenses." The system essentially penalizes debtors willing to downsize
their expenses because every penny earned, but not spent, must go to unsecured
creditors. This practice also leads to inconsistency in outcome since debtors with
less aggressive counsel or no counsel will have larger repayment obligations than
debtors with counsel who help them shelter their incomes.
Because a disposable income test encourages the incurrence of expenses that
many debtors have shown they cannot afford, one might surmise that the high
noncompletion rate in Chapter 13 is partly attributable to the structure of the
repayment system. By requiring a debtor to give up all income in excess of
"reasonably necessary expenses," the debtor may continue to incur obligations in excess
of her repayment capacity. When another financial setback occurs, the debtor has
less flexibility to deal with the problem either through modest savings or by reducing
payments to unsecured creditors. It thus is possible that the disposable income test
contributes to high noncompletion rate in Chapter 13.
To deal with the overwhelming confusion, some trustees or districts have
developed guidelines on acceptable necessary expenses to help the court and trustee
make the required value judgments on the debtor's lifestyle. (695) The guidelines may
ameliorate some inefficiencies of this process, but they create de facto rules that
differ widely even from judge to judge or trustee to trustee in the same district. Neither
the Bankruptcy Code nor local rules could ever provide a blueprint for determining
"reasonably necessary expenses" in a way that accounts for infinite regional, cultural,
and personal differences. What such attempts do, however, is provide an incentive
to build budgets around the rules to limit the amount of disposable income without
sacrificing the feasibility of the plan. (696) A debtor with good legal advice will budget
with two guiding principles: 1) list expenses in categories that a particular judge or
trustee thinks are reasonably necessary;(697) 2) list high enough expenses to leave no
disposable income. The resulting information on schedules and budgets filed with
the court has been likened to the "great American novel."(698) This practice is
inconsistent with the goal of promoting accurate disclosures and enhancing the
integrity of the system.
Perhaps because of these shortcomings, the disposable income requirement
has taken on an equally troubling counterpart in some jurisdictions. Some courts and
trustees have developed informal "guidelines" on the minimum percentage of
unsecured debt that must be committed to satisfy the good faith requirement. (699)
Some courts throughout the country will not confirm plans that provide less than a
certain percentage of repayment to unsecured creditors. A percentage requirement
creates an insurmountable barrier for debtors with no disposable income who seek
relief under Chapter 13, perhaps to save a home or a car by curing a default. Had the
debtor's case been assigned to another judge who will confirm plans that promise no
payments to unsecured creditors, the outcome would have been different. (700) Once again, extremely different legal rules are being applied to cases with similar sets of
facts. (701)
Notwithstanding the generic good faith requirement of section 1325(a)(3),
minimum repayment requirements appear to run directly counter to the premise of
the disposable income requirement because they focus on the amount owed to
creditors, not on the amount the debtor can pay. Higher percentage requirements
also do not necessarily correlate with higher actual returns to unsecured creditors
because debtors presently can cure a secured debt default and exit the Chapter 13
system before paying anything to unsecured creditors. High minimum payment
requirements may contribute to the high noncompletion rate in Chapter 13, where
more modest repayment plans might have been plausible for more debtors.
The Commission proposes a principled basis for determining unsecured
creditors' entitlements throughout the course of Chapter 13 plans. The
Recommendation diverges from both the statutory disposable income test and the
court-mandated percentage-of-debt tests. The Commission endorses the concept of
a standardized payment based on a graduated percentage of adjusted gross income.
A sample guideline that has provided a point of departure for the Commission's
discussion referred to nominal repayment by debtors with incomes below $20,000,
and a graduated repayment requirement climbing to about 5% of adjusted gross
income annually for debtors with incomes above $75,000. The percentage guideline
could be adjusted based on the number of dependents claimed for income tax
purposes. The Chapter 13 trustee would be responsible for verifying the debtor's
income and for reviewing the debtor's income annually for changes that might
necessitate modification of the required amounts upward or downward. To this end,
debtors would be expected to provide any supplementary documentation at the
request of the trustee.
The Chapter 13 trustee would monitor all debt repayments, as most do in the
current system, and would make the pro rata distributions to unsecured creditors,
including those holding nondischargeable debts. The trustee or any unsecured
creditor could file an objection to a plan that deviated from the guidelines. A court
would review such an objection to determine whether the circumstances justified the
deviation. For example, a lower percentage payment may be appropriate for a debtor
who faced extraordinary expenses because of a chronically ill dependent or if the
local cost of living was very high.
Several factors should be considered in determining the exact numbers to use
in the guideline. The proposed standardized payment is exclusively for unsecured
debts. Debtors often have substantial payments on home mortgages, car loans,
furniture loans, or priority debts. In addition, debtors would still be required to meet
the "best interest" test to confirm a Chapter 13 plan for both secured and unsecured
creditors. (702) This means, for example, that if the unsecured creditors would have
received more in a Chapter 7 liquidation, the debtor will have to pay more than the
income guideline amount to meet that requirement. Debtors also would be free to
pay more if they voluntarily chose to do so.
The recommended approach to Chapter 13 unsecured debt payments should
yield more certainty, while providing some flexibility when needed. It achieves
equity and consistency without forcing debtors into a cookie cutter mold of income
and expenses that others deem appropriate. While the outcomes will not be the same
in every case in a system dealing with so many different family circumstances, a
system that begins at a single point nationally and requires justification for deviation
should provide fairer and more predictable results to both debtors and creditors.
Creditors would benefit from this consistent approach because they could better
anticipate recoveries. This Recommendation should make case monitoring easier and
less expensive. Judicial resources also could be used more efficiently to decide other
legal disputes.
Income-based unsecured debt payments also should complement efforts to
improve debtors' budgeting practices, while they promote debtor autonomy in
determining what expenses fit their budgets. As part of the bargain in Chapter 13,
debtors would have a reasonable, fixed payment on their general unsecured debt
through the life of the plan (unless their adjusted gross incomes change) and could
budget accordingly. Because the amounts required by the guideline are a percentage
of income and not dollar for dollar, the system would not discourage a debtor from
increasing productivity. A debtor might use Chapter 13 as the time to make
sensible economic decisions, moving to a more modest apartment or driving a less
expensive car. The debtor would have an incentive to cut other costs to establish
long-term financial stability. Ultimately, this provision offers hope to increase the
success rate in Chapter 13, providing concomitant benefits for both debtors and
creditors. Some debtors' representatives have acknowledged that this approach
serves educational and rehabilitative functions by giving debtors incentives to be
more realistic about the house and car payments they can afford. (703)
A standardized approach to unsecured debt repayment has not been embraced
universally. Some lawyers, judges, and academics prefer the subjective approach to
determine the appropriate unsecured debt payment. (704) They have argued that more
plans may fail if the payments do not reflect a debtor's individual circumstances. A
debtor who cannot afford the amount prescribed by the guideline may also be unable
to afford to litigate eligibility for a variance.
In addition, because the unsecured debt payment generally would become
independent of other obligations, higher mortgage payments may render a plan
infeasible, and therefore some families will not be able to save their homes from
foreclosure. Debtors who have consolidated unsecured debts by taking another
mortgage are even more likely to have this problem. Thus, some would prefer that
actual housing costs be taken into account.
As an alternative, some might endorse an amendment to clearly establish that
courts are not to impose minimum debt percentages, but most likely would go no
further to change the current methods of determining unsecured debt payments.
Conversely, recently introduced legislation, The Responsible Borrower Protection
Bankruptcy Act, H.R. 2500, would substitute the disposable income requirement
with a "monthly net income" concept, which would entail a multi-step calculation
based on the Internal Revenue Service expenditure levels. (705)
The Commission's recommended guideline approach for unsecured debt
payment in Chapter 13 as not designed or intended to be applied to debtors in
Chapter 7 to determine whether they should be in Chapter 13. Unsecured debt
repayment requirements have played a part in the interpretation of a controversial
section of the Bankruptcy Code, section 707(b). Section 707 sets forth grounds for
dismissal of a Chapter 7 case, and subsection (b) authorizes the court or the U.S.
trustee to bring a motion to dismiss an individual's Chapter 7 case involving
primarily consumer debts if the case and the ultimate discharge of debt would be a
"substantial abuse" of Chapter 7.
Courts have been divided over whether ability to pay some portion of one's debts
is substantial abuse of the Chapter 7 discharge. Some courts, including the Eighth
and Ninth Circuit Courts of Appeals, have held that ability to pay a substantial
percentage of debt out of future income is grounds for dismissal of a Chapter 7
case. (706) Under this type of approach, some courts will find a Chapter 7 case to be
substantial abuse only if the debtor could have paid 100% of debts in a reasonable
period of time. (707) The Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit took a slightly broader
approach, but ultimately determined that the debtor's ability to repay may be
sufficient to support a finding of substantial abuse. The debtor's ability to pay would
be a mandatory consideration, but other factors could rebut whatever presumption of
substantial abuse was created by the debtor's apparent repayment ability. (708) Taking
a different course, the Court of Appeals for the Fourth Circuit has held that a Chapter
7 debtor's ability to repay a substantial percentage of debt, in itself, could not support
a finding of substantial abuse. (709) Rather, substantial abuse must be assessed on a
case-by-case basis in view of the "totality of circumstances" to see if the case is
abusive overall. (710) Under any of these approaches, courts that review cases for
repayment ability closely scrutinize the details of the life and expenses of the debtor
and related parties, (711) similar to the disposable income analysis. The inquiry is
heavily fact intensive and consumes substantial judicial resources when it arises.
The Commission's Consumer Bankruptcy Working Group discussed section
707(b), but did not make a recommendation on the appropriate interpretation or
changes to that provision. The Commission's endorsement of guidelines to replace
the problematic disposable income requirement was not intended to be applied to
Chapter 7 debtors to be a proxy for substantial abuse, for this would stretch the term
"substantial abuse" beyond recognition.
Note on Attorneys' Fees. The payment of attorneys' fees in Chapter 13 cases
presents distinct problems. Attorneys' fees payment methods in Chapter 13 currently
differ widely around the country. (712) Some courts treat attorneys' fees as
administrative expenses. (713) Other courts will stretch out attorneys' fees through the
life of the plan. (714) Still others allow certain plan payments to be applied exclusively
to attorneys' fees. (715) Each approach inherently involves different incentives. (716)
The Commission could find no specific justification for the diversity in
approaches, but it did not determine an appropriate single practice to recommend.
The Commission specifically sought further comment on this issue, although
received very little feedback; one attorney validated the notion that the treatment of
Chapter 13 cases and attorneys' fees varied from district to district and judge to
judge, and commented that some courts do not account sufficiently for the added
time and effort associated with diligent representation of a Chapter 13 debtor as
compared with a Chapter 7 debtor. (717)
1.5.5 Consequences of Incomplete Payment Plans
The Bankruptcy Code should provide that a case under Chapter 13 that
otherwise meets the standards for dismissal shall be converted to
Chapter 7 after notice and a hearing unless a party in interest objects on
the basis that the debtor had been granted a discharge in a Chapter 7
case commenced within six years of the date on which the conversion
would take place, in which case the Chapter 13 case will be dismissed.
In addition, the debtor may object to conversion without grounds, in
which case the Chapter 13 case will be dismissed. The standards for
modification, dismissal, and discharge in Chapter 13 would not
otherwise change.
Section 362 should be amended to provide that the filing of a petition by
an individual does not operate as a stay if the individual has filed two or
more petitions for relief under title 11 within six years of filing the
instant petition for relief and if the individual has been a debtor in a
bankruptcy case within 180 days prior to the instant petition for relief.
On the request of the debtor, after notice and a hearing, the court may
impose a stay for cause shown, subject to such conditions and
modifications as the court may impose.
About two-thirds of Chapter 13 cases are converted or dismissed before a
debtor completes repayment of a plan of reorganization. The Commission's
Recommendations are designed to encourage and enable plan completion by
requiring a full term to cure and reinstate secured debt and by standardizing the
unsecured debt payment. Even so, nothing can guarantee that consumer debtors will
always be able to complete their Chapter 13 plans successfully. Another financial
bump in the road can easily derail a consumer plan, especially when a debtor has
little financial reserve. A lost job or an unexpected expenses can quickly change the
feasibility of a plan.
When a debtor ceases making plan payments, several consequences can
follow under current law. The plan can be modified or suspended for a period of
time if requested. (718) Alternatively, the debtor may convert the case to a Chapter 7
liquidation. (719) If a debtor can establish certain facts, the debtor might be entitled to
a "hardship discharge" of debts that would have been discharged in a Chapter 7
case. (720) The debtor, the trustee, or a creditor may ask that the case be dismissed, with
no discharge of debt. (721)
If the debtor is advised by a careful lawyer, the option chosen will reflect the
debtor's particular situation. A short-term setback in income might justify a minor
modification or several month suspension. On the other hand, a significant financial
setback or complete infeasibility may lead the diligent debtor's attorney to seek
conversion to Chapter 7 or a "hardship discharge" in Chapter 13.
However, not all debtors are represented after their plans are confirmed and
payments have commenced. Some debtors never had legal help, and others have no
continuing relationship with the lawyers who helped them file the initial papers and appeared with them at the meeting of creditors. For debtors
without careful advice, the default position under current law is dismissal of the case
with no discharge of any debt. Thus, after paying a filing fee, attorneys' fees, and
several months or years of payments under the plan, the debtor may be back where
she started. In fact, the debtor may be more financially burdened than at the time of
the filing due to liability for unpaid unsecured debts including compounded interest
that has accrued since the case commenced. If a debtor later realizes that she
experienced only a short term setback and wants to try again to repay, or if she needs
a discharge to prevent the collection efforts that initially drove her to the bankruptcy
system, she will have to pay another filing fee and potentially another attorneys' fee
to re-enter Chapter 13.
This situation highlights several shortcomings of the current system. The
complexity of the system prevents the people most in need of relief from receiving
it. More sophisticated debtors with good legal advice can make the proper choices.
Other debtors are ousted from the system after paying a filing fee and adding to the
administrative burden of the bankruptcy system. They will face substantial costs if
they attempt to re-enter: debtors' limited resources are allocated to multiple filing fees
and attorneys' fees rather than to creditors or to the debtor's financial rehabilitation.
To help address these problems, the Commission does not introduce a new
rule, but rather, recommends changing the default rule when a Chapter 13 plan
languishes. Rather than penalizing debtors who attempted to repay their debts in
Chapter 13, (722) the system should give them the discharge they would have received
had they originally filed under Chapter 7. The Commission recommends that absent
an affirmative step by the debtor to modify, suspend, or dismiss, failure of a Chapter
13 plan presumptively should lead to conversion to Chapter 7. Conversion would
occur only after an opportunity for notice and hearing, and a debtor's case could not
be converted if the debtor was barred from receiving a Chapter 7 on account of a
prior Chapter 7 case. If a national filing system is implemented, as the Commission
recommends, this fact easily would be discovered. A debtor would retain the option
to have a Chapter 13 case dismissed without converting to Chapter 7. This route
might be sensible for someone who secured lucrative employment and preferred to
work with her creditors under state law.
The Commission does not propose a new option. The Code already provides
an unequivocal and nonwaivable right to convert from Chapter 13 to Chapter 7. (723)
Yet, under the current system, a debtor needs to know enough about the bankruptcy
system to request such relief, and many do not. According to an analysis of
termination data for Chapter 13 cases filed between 1980 and 1988 conducted by the
Administrative Office of the U.S. Courts, dismissal was the most common
disposition of Chapter 13 cases: 49% were dismissed, whereas only 14% were
converted to Chapter 7. (724) Only 36% received a discharge at all. (725)
This Recommendation is similar in intent, but slightly different in detail to
a proposal adopted by the Consumer Bankruptcy Reform Forum of the American
Bankruptcy Institute, which involved approximately 50 practitioners, judges,
academics, trustees and others representing the views of both debtors and creditors. (726) This
group recommended that a debtor in an uncompleted Chapter 13 receive a Chapter
7-type discharge in Chapter 13 due to concerns about paying the Chapter 7 trustee to
administer the estate in a no-asset case when there is no new filing fee. In effect, the
ABI proposes that the Chapter 13 trustee serve the supervisory functions of the
Chapter 7 trustee.
Repeat Access
The combination of easy access to Chapter 13 and a high noncompletion rate
leads to the possibility of a significant number of repeat bankruptcy filings. While
the data are sparse because of the lack of a centralized filing system, various efforts
have been made to determine the extent to which debtors enter the bankruptcy system
multiple times. (727) According to both formal and informal surveys, Chapter 13 trustees in various regions appear to see widely divergent numbers of repeat filers,
with the responders identifying anywhere from 1% to 40% their cases being filed by
individuals who have been debtors previously. (728)
It is equally and perhaps more significant to determine why debtors file more
than once, an analysis that has been undertaken by some judges and scholars. (729)
People take different views on whether repeated access to consumer bankruptcy relief
is abusive, but the answer to that question is often fact-specific. Parties file for
bankruptcy relief repeatedly for different reasons. Among the possibilities:
Changing employment circumstances, family crises, or persistent
financial difficulties cause some debtors to fall in arrears in their
Chapter 13 plans. They may not be aware of the option to suspend or
modify, or the problem may not appear to have an end in sight. These
debtors may see their plans dismissed, and they may file again later
to make another attempt to repay when their circumstances improve.
Similarly, debtors might have been overly optimistic about their
future earnings and ability to fund substantial plan payments.
Some debtors file more than once because their first trip through
bankruptcy failed to give them adequate debt relief. A debtor might
file for Chapter 7, for example, but emerge with an inadequate
discharge because the debtor reaffirmed too much debt, leading to
future financial distress. Other debtors might emerge from Chapter 7
still burdened with debt because they received erroneous or
inadequate advice about whether their debts were dischargeable in
Chapter 7 (or at all) or too quickly settled with creditors threatening
to file nondischargeability actions. Still in need of debt relief, a
person in this situation might file a Chapter 13.
A portion of the Chapter 13 debtors do not have positive net income and
need a Chapter 7 discharge, but due to external encouragement or
moral compulsion, they make ill-fated attempts to pay debts in
Chapter 13. When no one recognizes the problem before the case is
dismissed (in which case a conversion would have been in order),
these debtors pay another filing fee and file a Chapter 7 to get the
discharge they needed to deal with their initial financial collapse.
Alternatively, not realizing that they still lack the wherewithal to fund
a Chapter 13 plan, such debtors might make a second (or third)
attempt at repayment in Chapter 13.
Cases may be dismissed and refiled when courts use
dismissal as a disciplinary tool. A debtor may miss any number of
time deadlines or unintentionally fail to comply with administrative
requirements, such as appearing at the section 341 meeting of
creditors, filing tax returns, and providing requested information to
the trustee. (730)
While each of these examples of debtors who are in the system for a second
or third time point out weaknesses in the system, such as inadequate supervision of
reaffirmations or inadequate counseling for debtors in financial trouble, other debtors
in the system are not looking for a discharge or a repayment mechanism. These
circumstances highlight other weaknesses in the consumer bankruptcy system.
Some debtors file for Chapter 13 only to obtain access to the special
tools offered in Chapter 13, such as the stripdown and deacceleration
of secured debt and treatment of taxes, to deal with certain creditors
but are not committed to making the scheduled payments that
accompany these benefits for the full term of the plan. (731) By filing,
they get the benefit of the automatic stay, negotiate with that one
creditor, and then allow their cases to be dismissed. If the negotiated deal does not
work, they file again to obtain another automatic stay to repeat the
negotiation process. The lack of discharge accompanying dismissal
enables these debtors to file again, potentially for the same reasons.
Others file on the eve of a foreclosure or eviction for the sole purpose
of delaying the state legal process. (732) When the threat passes, they
dismiss their cases, only to file again when the mortgagee or landlord
brings another legal action to seize control of the property. The
ability to file repeatedly for Chapter 13 relief increases a debtor's
leverage in negotiations with creditors. In regions where this problem
is particularly acute, judges have devoted significant time and
resources to developing tools to address this problem. (733)
Other debtors file Chapter 7 cases to be relieved of dischargeable
debts and personal liability, followed by Chapter 13 to restructure
secured and nondischargeable debts. (734) This "Chapter 20" changes
the bargain contemplated in Chapter 13. Alternatively, a debtor
might use this approach to bring all debts within the Chapter 13
limits. (735)
Whatever the cause of the dismissal and refiling, debtors may decide not to
request a discharge if they are not being pursued by creditors and thus can retain the
possibility of refiling. When they refile rather than modify, they can include debt
incurred after the first filing in the next repayment plan, albeit with the cost of a new
filing fee and perhaps new attorneys' fees. In addition, a debtor who was in
substantial arrears in her first Chapter 13 plan, yet had the opportunity to modify,
might choose to dismiss and refile. This might yield smaller monthly payments than
curing the first plan.
The Commission originally recommended a two-year bar on refilings,
regardless of the disposition of the prior case. (736) This recommendation was endorsed
by home mortgage lenders, who seem to have had particularly trying experiences
with repeat filings that delay foreclosure sales. (737) This approach was similar to that
proposed by Senators Reid and Brown several years ago that would have limited a
debtor's eligibility to file a Chapter 13 petition to once every three years. (738) While
stressing the importance of providing a fresh start to individual debtors, Senator Reid
cited the high failure rate of Chapter 13 and questioned the advantages and propriety
of permitting continuous access to the bankruptcy system; this amendment would
"say to all debtors: You are now in the court of last resort, and because we are
granting you the absolute, unquestioned protection of the automatic stay, you will be
given one opportunity to reorganize your finances for at least every three years."(739)
However, other senators did not support restricting a debtor's subsequent efforts to
pay creditors through the Chapter 13 repayment mechanism, and felt that the
evidence was not sufficiently overwhelming to justify this substantial change, (740) and
the amendment was not adopted. (741) Similarly, the Commission revisited its
recommendation on a two year ban and opted for a different approach.
A significant restriction on access to bankruptcy or to the automatic stay
indeed would be an historic change. The evidence still is not sufficiently conclusive
on the prevalence of each of the aforementioned causes of refiling to warrant a drastic
change in access when a more moderate approach would suffice. (742) At the same
time, frequent and repetitive access to the tools of bankruptcy should be discouraged
if one trip to the bankruptcy system provides the relief that Congress intended. Thus,
rather than advocating a flat two-year ban, the Commission recommends a more
moderate change to deter successive filings. A debtor would not be precluded from
filing two petitions within a six-year time frame. If a debtor sought bankruptcy relief
for the third time in six years, and within six months of the dismissal or conversion
of the second filing, the filing would not trigger an automatic stay. (743) The bankruptcy
court clerk's office would not send notice of the bankruptcy to the debtor's creditors,
and thus no creditor actions would be halted, unless the court subsequently ordered
that a stay be imposed. The debtor would have the burden of persuading the court
to enter that stay order. This approach should discourage a debtor from filing a
nonmeritorious third or subsequent petition on the eve of a foreclosure sale merely
to stay the sale, (744) and thus deals with one of the most frequently cited uses of repeat
Chapter 13 filings.
The Recommendation contemplates that other parts of the Chapter 7 and
Chapter 13 system would not be changed. The grounds for dismissing or converting
a Chapter 13 case, for example, would remain intact, as would the effects of
dismissal and conversion. Similarly, the Recommendation does not change either the
current "best interest" standard or the Chapter 7 requirements for debtors whose
cases were converted from Chapter 13.
1.5.6 In Rem Orders
Section 362 should be amended to provide that the filing of a petition by
an individual does not operate as a stay with respect to property of the
estate transferred to that individual by another individual who was a
debtor under title 11 within 180 days of the filing of the instant petition,
unless the court grants a stay with respect to such property after notice
and a hearing on request of the debtor.
After notice and a hearing, a bankruptcy court should be empowered to
issue in rem orders barring the application of a future automatic stay to
identified property of the estate for a period of up to six years when a
party could show that the debtor had transferred such real property or
leasehold interests or fractional shares of property or leasehold interests
to avoid creditor foreclosure or eviction. A subsequent owner of the
property or tenant of the leasehold who files for bankruptcy (or the same
owner or holder in a subsequent filing) should be permitted to petition
the bankruptcy court for the imposition of a stay to protect property of
the estate, which the court would be required to grant to protect
innocent parties who were not a part of a scheme to transfer the
property to hinder foreclosure or eviction.
Judges, practitioners, and creditor representatives in some regions of the
country have reported on a scheme that uses the bankruptcy process to prevent
foreclosure sales repeatedly. The property owner makes a gift of, or assigns for little
or nominal consideration, fractional interests in the property to related individuals or
entities on the eve of foreclosure. (745) One of the transferees then files a Chapter 13
petition immediately after receipt of its fractional interest, thereby staying the
foreclosure sale. In the typical case, the transferee does not fulfill the duties imposed
on the debtor by the Bankruptcy Code. The transferee may fail to attend the first
meeting of creditors or to file its schedules. Consequently, often before the creditor
can obtain relief from the automatic stay, the transferee's bankruptcy case is
dismissed on motion of the trustee. Following the dismissal, the creditor cannot
simply resume the foreclosure process. The transferee can attempt to file a new
bankruptcy case if such action has not been barred, a situation that is addressed in the
prior Recommendation. In the alternative, after the transferee's first bankruptcy case
has been dismissed, the property owner can transfer another fractional interest in the
property to a new individual or entity, who then files a bankruptcy petition, causing
the automatic stay to be imposed against the same property. Like the previous
transferee, this transferee will make no progress in the bankruptcy case, and the case
will be dismissed. The scheme can continue indefinitely, delaying the foreclosure
sale, and increasing the costs for the creditor. (746) In some instances, the creditor
succeeds in obtaining relief from the stay, and forecloses on the property. However,
if the owner has assigned fractional interests in the property, it is likely that the
assignee did not receive notice of the foreclosure sale. Thus, the sale is vulnerable
to attack, while the creditor's costs continue to mount.
Landlords also have reported to the Commission that they are having
difficulty with the wrongful use of Chapter 13 to obtain the automatic stay. (747) As
with an ownership interest, parties can transfer shares of the leasehold interest, or
place multiple names on the lease, and then each individual or entity sequentially
files a Chapter 13 petition, to prevent eviction. By doing so, the parties avoid paying
rent while also repeatedly preventing eviction. This practice is most harmful to small
landlords with limited holdings who cannot absorb the cost of perennially non-paying
tenants.
The transfer of fractional shares by owners or tenants to frustrate lenders' or
landlords' exercise of remedies provided under state law is inappropriate. Chapter
13 should not be used in furtherance of this scheme. (748) Although the practice is rare,
and, according to the testimony presented to the Commission, geographically limited,
it is an indefensible abuse of the bankruptcy system and should be prohibited before
it spreads. (749) The Commission recommends empowering bankruptcy judges to issue in rem orders to eradicate this practice.
Anin rem order permits the court to grant prospective relief from the
automatic stay in connection with identified property. The order will bind any party
claiming an interest in that property and will also prevent the property from
becoming part of a bankruptcy estate in a subsequent case. These in rem orders could
be filed in the state property recording system to provide notice to purchasers and
other parties.
Some courts already issue in rem orders under the apparent authority of state
property law. (750) Other courts addressing the issue have been troubled by issues of
due process, namely, limiting the rights of subsequent transferees, or co-owners,
without notice having been provided to them. (751) The Commission takes no position
with respect to current practices regarding in rem orders. However, the Commission
has recommended elsewhere in this report that prospective court orders limiting a
debtor's rights and obligations in bankruptcy are unenforceable except as authorized
by Title 11. (752) If Congress adopts that Recommendation, a specific amendment authorizing these prospective orders also will be required.
In explaining the problems with tenants filing bankruptcy to delay
foreclosure, landlords have requested a different type of statutory relief. They have
sought an exception to the automatic stay for month-to-month leases. (753) This type of
change would entitle a landlord to evict an individual or family in bankruptcy while
all other creditor actions were stayed. The landlords argue that they need speedy,
cheap access to state eviction proceedings, and that the automatic stay delays them
and drives up costs. With an exception to the stay, they reason that they would have
no need to go to court and file a motion to terminate the automatic stay in order to
continue with eviction proceedings.
There is substantial evidence that an exception to the automatic stay would
not accomplish the result for which the landlords strive. A similar exception to the
automatic stay to benefit nonresidential landlords has not kept them out of court.
Section 362(b)(10) excepts nonresidential leases that were "terminated" prior to the
bankruptcy filing. (754) Although section 362(b)(10) was intended to provide landlords
with expedient resolution in state court to reclaim property, (755) the published case law
suggests that the provision has not insulated landlords from time-consuming
proceedings in the bankruptcy courts. (756) It is even more likely that the same issue
would arise in consumer cases due, in part, to the sheer volume and also to the
enhanced protections and elaborate procedures of state law to protect residential
tenants. The potential disputes can be predicted by evaluating the litigation that
occurs under section 365(a) when courts must determine whether a lease is unexpired
under applicable state law. (757) An amendment to section 362 is unlikely to accomplish
the intended goal of reducing costs and litigation for residential landlords. The in
rem and repeat filing proposals instead will provide tailored relief when needed.
Measures other than a statutory landlord exception can effectively curtail this
problem. Indeed, even in the Central District of California where the problem is
most prevalent, the court's Ad Hoc Committee on Unlawful Detainer reported in
January of 1997 that the rate of bankruptcy cases filed to delay eviction had dropped
significantly since 1991. (758)
Carving out residential leases from the collective bankruptcy proceeding
would have significant consequences to families in bankruptcy as well as their other
creditors in the collective bankruptcy proceeding. The fundamental purpose of the
automatic stay is to provide a breathing spell for the debtor while the creditors all are
assured that all other creditors are stayed from pursuing the debtor. All creditors are
significantly disadvantaged if this aspect of the debtor's financial life is carved out
of the bankruptcy process.
The Commission's Recommendation may not solve completely the problem
created by fractionalized ownership because some parties question the effect of in
rem orders on fractionalized interest transferees who recorded the grants before
recordation of the bankruptcy court's order, and thus potentially have a due process
argument that they are not bound without being brought before the court to bind
them. Others do not perceive a constitutional difficulty in binding pre-order
transferees; when the court issues the in rem order, the pre-order transferees receive
constitutionally-adequate notice and a hearing.
Effect of Payment under Chapter 13 Plans
1.5.7 Retention of the "Superdischarge"
Congress should retain 11 U.S.C. § 1328(a), which permits a debtor who
completes all payments under the plan to discharge all debts provided
for by the plan or disallowed under section 502 of title 11 except for
those listed in section 1328(a)(1) - (3).
The Bankruptcy Code presently provides that many debts nondischargeable
in Chapter 7 are dischargeable upon completion of a Chapter 13 payment plan. This
so-called "superdischarge" allows the discharge of all debts except for family support
obligations, drunk driving debts, student loans, criminal restitution, and debts that
must be paid on a priority basis in the Chapter 13 plan. (759) In essence, Chapter 13
allows for certain debts to be "worked off" over three to five years, thus providing
an incentive for plan completion by debtors who are able to repay debts in Chapter
13 and making some debts dischargeable only after a substantial repayment period.
Most debtors get no special benefit from the Chapter 13 superdischarge.
Whether or not they have nondischargeable debts, they do not receive a Chapter 13
superdischarge because they do not complete their Chapter 13 plans. (760) Among the
debtors who complete plans, the data are insufficient to determine how many
otherwise nondischargeable debts are discharged. Parties generally do not litigate
dischargeability when the debtor files for Chapter 13 because the superdischarge
vitiates the need for that litigation, thus there may never be reliable data to explain
how many debtors use the superdischarge provision. Notwithstanding the fact that
the majority of debtors do not obtain or have reason to obtain a superdischarge, the
issue is somewhat controversial. (761)
Some commentators advocate elimination of the superdischarge so that an
individual debtor is entitled the same discharge in any chapter. Parties support this
position on public policy and pragmatic grounds: if public policy requires a debt to
be singled out and excluded from discharge in Chapter 7, the debt should be repaid
regardless of whether the debtor undertakes a repayment plan and pays a potentially
nominal amount to all creditors. (762) This argument is bolstered by the fact that under
the current system, debtors may be able to discharge a significant nondischargeable
obligation by undertaking a payment plan that repays little or no unsecured debt. (763)
Spreading repayment to all creditors rather than focusing repayment on debts
incurred through wrongdoing arguably is not a reasonable trade-off, according to this
argument. Although someone with a very large nondischargeable debt will not be
a candidate for the superdischarge because of the debt eligibility limits, (764) the
underlying policy message remains a concern.
The superdischarge has been particularly controversial in the context of tax
debts. Some take issue with the notion that Chapter 13 debtors should be excused
from paying their entire tax debt. (765) Taking a different angle on the tax issue, others
perceive the superdischarge as a mechanism to provide a manageable re-entry to the
tax system, with the end result of being a powerful method of tax collection at low
cost to the taxing authorities. A judge from Northern California reported to the
Commission that in the bankruptcy cases in San Jose alone, Chapter 13 yielded $4.2
million for the Internal Revenue Service in 12 months. (766) The Chapter 13
superdischarge gives people a method to get back into the tax system without facing
overwhelming long-past-due liabilities that they could never repay.
Superdischarge supporters argue that the superdischarge is consistent with
Congressional intent to build in incentives for debtors to choose Chapter 13 over
Chapter 7. If an individual with a nondischargeable debt files for Chapter 13 in the
absence of a superdischarge, she will pay all creditors for three to five years and then
be required to continue paying nondischargeable debts for years into the future.
Because constraints on Chapter 13 plans may preclude the debtor from making full
payment of a nondischargeable debt during the life of the plan, and because some
courts permit interest to accrue on nondischargeable debts during the time the
bankruptcy is pending, debtors sometimes end up owing more nondischargeable debt
at the end of a plan than at the beginning. (767) These onerous circumstances hardly
provide a reasonable incentive for a debtor to choose Chapter 13. Rather, Chapter
7 would be the far more economially rational route for the debtor. In Chapter 7, the
debtor will discharge all other debts and can dedicate future income exclusively to
the nondischargeable debt. However, if Chapter 13 provides a superdischarge, a
debtor has an incentive to file for Chapter 13 and remit payment to all creditors for
three to five years. Potential abuses of the system are kept in check by the good faith
confirmation requirement.
Some people also argue that permitting the Chapter 13 debtor to discharge
otherwise nondischargeable debt upon completion of a plan vitiates the need for
litigation over whether a particular debt was nondischargeable and provides an
additional incentive to make every attempt to complete the plan. If a creditor alleged
that a debtor made a false representation, for example, the debtor who can afford
litigation expenses could contest the charge. However, the debtor who cannot afford
to litigate, but who has a regular income sufficient to fund a Chapter 13 plan, could
undertake a Chapter 13 plan. If the debtor completes the plan, the debt will be
discharged regardless of the allegation of false representation. If these debts were
nondischargeable in Chapter 13, costs to defend nondischargeability actions would
be diverted from income otherwise available to creditors, which might make the plan
infeasible. This might prevent debtors from contesting even nonmeritorious
nondischargeability allegations.
For these reasons, some parties endorsed expansion of the superdischarge for
longer plans, enabling additional debts to be dischargeable in Chapter 13, to provide
a greater incentive to use Chapter 13. (768) This change would have restored the superdischarge more to its original form.
In considering the strong views favoring and opposing the superdischarge, the
Commission took a middle ground. The Commission declined to change the form
of the superdischarge. (769) By allowing the discharge in Chapter 13 of some debt that
would be nondischargeable in Chapter 7, this provision encourages voluntary
Chapter 13 filings, more distributions to the creditor body as a whole, and economic
rehabilitation of the debtor through improved budget practices and a fresher start.
Certain debts paid on a priority basis ahead of other unsecured claims retain their
nondischargeable status in all chapters.
1.5.8 Debtors who choose Chapter 13 repayment plans should have their
bankruptcy filings reported differently from those who do not. Debtors
who complete voluntary debtor education programs should have that
fact noted on their credit reports.
Federal law permits credit reporting agencies to report Chapter 7 or Chapter
13 filings on debtors' credit reports for up to ten years. Federal law requires credit
reports to distinguish between Chapter 7 and Chapter 13 only "if provided by the
source of the information."(770) Moreover, few credit reporters identify debtors who
tried to repay or even those who, in fact, completed substantial repayments. (771) One
of the ironies of the current bankruptcy system is that debtors who try to repay their
debts in Chapter 13 may have worse credit histories than those who quickly discharge
debts in Chapter 7. (772)
Additional and refined information in the credit reporting system would help
debtors re-establish credit following bankruptcy and help creditors make more
informed credit-granting decisions. The fact that the debtor completed a financial
education program also would be useful information for creditors making subsequent
lending decisions. (773)
Differential reporting would give debtors a powerful incentive to undertake
repayment in Chapter 13 that they might otherwise not attempt. (774) If the credit
reporting and credit granting systems continue to favor Chapter 7 debtors, debtors
who do have regular income and the means to repay a portion of their debts may be
less inclined for fear of adverse future credit consequences.
Debtors' credit reports also should reflect when debtors do not discharge any
debt. For example, if a debtor is repaying debts in a Chapter 13 plan, obtains a high
paying job, and decides to dismiss the case and work with his creditors under state
law, the debtor should be sure to provide documentation so that the debtor's credit
report reflects this fact.
The Commission recommends that the Fair Credit Reporting Act be amended
to provide that debtors who choose Chapter 13 repayment plans and make payments
have their bankruptcy filings reported differently from those who do not. (775) This
Recommendation does not entail the elimination of the recording of the filing.
Rather, the Commission endorses the inclusion of repayment information. The
Consumer Bankruptcy Reform Forum of the American Bankruptcy Institute
unanimously endorsed this recommended change in credit reporting. (776) This
emphasis on reestablishing a good credit record should not be construed to mean that
credit access is more important than savings or learning to live more on a cash basis.
Indeed, understanding credit (its benefits, costs and risks), savings and proper
budgeting should be key subjects of any educational program that is developed.
1.5.9 Trustees should be encouraged to establish credit rehabilitation
programs to help provide better, cheaper access to credit for those who
participate in repayment plans.
Partly due to credit reporting, former Chapter 13 debtors historically have
experienced difficulty obtaining credit even after completing repayment plans.
Restrictions on access to credit are not quite as acute as they once were, but obtaining
reasonably priced credit is sometimes harder for Chapter 13 debtors than for Chapter
7 debtors. A few Chapter 13 trustees have instituted credit rehabilitation programs. (777) These programs, through the use of "credit liaisons," help Chapter 13 debtors
assess their future credit needs and match that consumer with an appropriate credit
grantor to obtain credit at more appropriate rates. A credit rehabilitation program
also might help debtors obtain, interpret, and update their credit records.
Credit grantors seem willing to assist consumers with reestablishing their
credit through this type of mechanism. (778) The current programs could provide a
model for study as trustees take on this important task.
Trustees may opt to experiment with the level of repayment required for
debtors to engage in this program. Very high repayment percentages--from 75-100%--appear to be required. (779) Other districts may find that debtors who diligently
attempt to repay their debts, even if they cannot repay this high a percentage, can be
assisted with credit reestablishment as well.
Like with financial education, the uncertain authority to expend funds to run
these programs prevents more widespread development of credit rehabilitation. The
Commission therefore recommends that this type of program be explicitly
recognized. The opportunity to reestablish credit might provide an additional
incentive for debtors to not only attempt repayment, but to do their best to complete
their plans.
Annex A
Proposed Statutory Language for 11 U.S.C. § 524(c)
11 U.S.C. § 524(c): An agreement between a holder of a claim and the debtor, the
consideration for which, in whole or in part, is based on a debt that is dischargeable
in a case under this title is enforceable only if:
1) the agreement was made and has been filed with the court before the
granting of the discharge;
2) the agreement contains a clear and conspicuous statement advising the
debtor that the agreement is not required under this title, nonbankruptcy law,
or any agreement not in accordance with the provisions of this section, and
that the agreement may be rescinded at any time prior to discharge or within
60 days after the agreement is filed with the court, whichever occurs later,
by giving notice of rescission to the holder of such claim;
3) the amount of the debt that the debtor seeks to reaffirm does not exceed the
allowed secured claim, the lien is not avoidable under the provisions of this
title, no attorney fees, costs, or expenses have been added to the principal
amount of the debt to be reaffirmed, and the agreement stipulates that the
lien will be released after the payment of the debt that the debtor has
reaffirmed;
4) the motion for approval of the agreement is accompanied by underlying
contractual documents and all related security agreements or liens, together
with evidence of their perfection, and the debtor has provided all information
requested in the motion for approval of the agreement;
5) if the debtor is represented by an attorney in negotiations on the agreement,
the agreement is accompanied by a declaration or affidavit of the attorney
stating that:
(A) the agreement is voluntary;
(B) the agreement does not impose undue hardship on the debtor or the
debtor's dependents;
(C) the agreement is, in the view of the attorney, in the best interest of the
debtor and the debtor's dependents; and
(D) the attorney fully advised the debtor of the legal effect and
consequences of such an agreement and the consequences of default
and alternatives to reaffirmation, such as redemption under section
722 of this title;
6) the court has held a hearing at its discretion or if required under subsection
(d) of this section, reviewed the agreement and its terms and has approved
the agreement as being consistent with this section and the provisions of this
title; and
7) the debtor has not rescinded the agreement at any time prior to discharge or
within 60 days after such agreement is filed with the court, whichever occurs
later, by giving notice of rescission to the holder of such claim.
Annex B
Proposed Statutory Language for 11 U.S.C. § 524(d)
11 U.S.C. § 524(d): In a case concerning an individual, when the court has
determined whether to grant or not to grant a discharge under section 727, 1141,
1228, or 1328 of this title, the court may hold a hearing at which the debtor shall
appear in person. At any such hearing, the court shall inform the debtor that a
discharge has been granted or the reason why a discharge has not been granted. If
the debtor seeks to make an agreement of the kind specified in subsection (c) of this
section, a hearing on the proposed agreement is not required when:
1) the debtor was represented by an attorney in negotiations on the agreement
and the debtor's attorney has signed the affidavit as provided in section
524(c);
2) the agreement has been made prior to the date of the debtor's discharge; and
3) a party in interest has not requested a judicial valuation of the collateral that
is the subject of the agreement.
If one or more of the foregoing factors is not satisfied, or in the court's discretion,
the court shall conduct a hearing to determine whether the agreement should be
approved. At this hearing, the court shall inform the debtor that the agreement is not
required under this title, under nonbankruptcy law, or under any agreement not
made in accordance with the provisions of subsection (c) of this section. The court
shall explain the legal effects and consequences of the agreement and of a default
under such an agreement. In addition to meeting all requirements of subsection (c),
an agreement can be approved after a hearing only if the court has determined that:
1) the agreement is in the best interest of the debtor and the debtor's
dependents; and
2) the agreement will not impose an undue hardship on the debtor and the
debtor's dependents in light of the debtor's income and expenses.
Annex C
Proposed Requirements for Motion for Approval of Reaffirmation Agreements
The motion for approval should include the following information:
- Name of the parties.
- Summary terms of new agreement, including the principal amount, the
interest rate (APR), the amount of monthly payment, the date on which
payments will commence, the total number of payments, the total amount of
payments (interest and principal) if paid according to schedule and the date
on which the lien will be released, whether payments were in default as of
bankruptcy filing, and ways in which terms differ from original agreement.
- Description of security, including manufacturer, year, and model if
applicable, value of security and the basis for the parties' determination of
that value, and current and anticipated use of collateral.
- The effect of the proposed reaffirmation on the debtor, including information
on the debtor's monthly income and expenses, whether the agreement will
impose an undue hardship on the debtor, the reasons for the debtor entering
into this agreement, whether the agreement is in the debtor's best interest,
and whether the debtor considered the option of redemption under section
722.
- Whether the agreement is part of a settlement of litigation on the
dischargeability of this debt under section 523 of the Bankruptcy Code.
- Whether the debtor was represented by an attorney during the course of the
negotiations on the agreement.
- A statement of the parties' understanding that the agreement is entirely
voluntary and is not required, that the debtor may rescind the agreement at
any time prior to discharge or within 60 days after agreement is filed,
whichever is later, and that the agreement will be fully enforceable under
state law.
- Certification of the parties that they have attached the instrument creating
the debt and any security interest or lien along with any documents necessary
to show perfection of the interest.
Annex D
State Homestead Exemptions Order of Value as Applicable to Joint Debtors
Under Sixty Years of Age with Two Dependents in Non-Rural Region(780)
State | Exemption | Opt-Out? |
Florida | Unlimited $ Amount | Yes |
Iowa | Unlimited $ Amount | Yes |
Kansas | Unlimited $ Amount | Yes |
South Dakota | Unlimited $ Amount | Yes |
Texas | Unlimited $ Amount | No |
Minnesota | $200,000 | No |
Nevada | $125,000 | Yes |
Arizona | $100,000 | Yes |
Massachusetts | $100,000 ($200,000 if debtor is over 65) | No |
North Dakota | $80,000 | Yes |
California | $75,000 ($100,000 if debtor is over 65) | Yes |
Connecticut | $75,000 | No |
Mississippi | $75,000 | Yes |
New Mexico | $60,000 ($30,000 per joint tenant) | No |
Alaska | $54,000 | Ambiguous/Probably Yes |
Idaho | $50,000 | Yes |
Montana | $40,000 | Yes |
Wisconsin | $40,000 | No |
Wyoming | $40,000 ($10,000 per "occupant") | Yes |
Oregon | $33,000 | Yes |
Colorado | $30,000 | Yes |
Hawaii | $30,000 | No |
New Hampshire | $30,000 | No |
Vermont | $30,000 | No |
Washington | $30,000 | No |
New York | $20,000 | Yes |
Indiana | $15,000 ($7,500 per debtor) | Yes |
Louisiana | $15,000 | Yes |
Maine | $12,500 | Yes |
Utah | $11,000 (with spouse and dependents) | Yes |
Alabama | $10,000 ($5,000 per debtor) | Yes |
Georgia | $10,000 ($5,000 per debtor) | Yes |
Nebraska | $10,000 | Yes |
North Carolina | $10,000 | Yes |
South Carolina | $10,000 (if co-owners) | Yes |
Missouri | $8,000 | Yes |
Illinois | $7,500 | Yes |
Tennessee | $7,500 | Yes |
West Virginia | $7,500 | Yes |
Virginia | $6,500 (head of household and 3 depend-ents; can be used for personal property too) | Yes |
Kentucky | $5,000 | Yes |
Ohio | $5,000 | Yes |
Oklahoma | $5,000 (unlimited for rural) | Yes |
Michigan | $3,500 | No |
Arkansas | $2,500 | No |
District of Columbia | None (except condo escrow deposits) | No |
Delaware | None (but provides $10,000 lump sum exemption that may be applicable) | Yes |
Maryland | None (but provides $5,500 wildcard exemption for property of any kind) | Yes |
New Jersey | No Homestead Exemption | No |
Pennsylvania | No Homestead Exemption | No |
Rhode Island | No Homestead Exemption | No |
Notes:
601 See Henry H. Haden, Chapter XIII Wage Earner Plans-Forgotten Man Bankruptcy, 55 Ky. L. J. 564 (1966).
Return to text
602 Teresa A. Sullivan, Elizabeth Warren, & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Persistence of Local
Legal Culture: Twenty Years of Evidence from the Federal Bankruptcy Courts, 17 HARV. J. L. & PUB.
POL. 801, 843 (1994). The 1970 Commission noted that in some areas, debtors may not be aware of
any option to them under the Bankruptcy Act except Chapter XIII. REPORT OF THE
COMMISSION ON THE BANKRUPTCY LAWS OF THE UNITED STATES, H.R. DOC. No. 93-137, 158 (1973). See also Michael Bork & Susan D. Tuck, Administrative Office of the United States Courts, Bankruptcy Statistical Trends: Chapter
13; Adjustment of Debts of an Individual with Regular Income (Working Paper 1), (Jan. 1994)
(finding that Chapter 13 most commonly found in Southeastern states, excluding Florida, and that
Chapter 13 cases had accounted for more than 50% of total case filings since 1981 in nine districts,
eight of which were in Southeastern states, and that Chapter 13 filings in Alabama, Tennessee,
Georgia and North Carolina had increased steadily as percentage of total filings since 1988, reaching
combined 61 % in 1993).
Return to text
603 Michael Bork and Susan D. Tuck, Administrative Office of the U.S. Courts, Bankruptcy
Statistical Trends; Chapter 13; Dispositions (Working Paper 2) (October 1994) (studying termination
data for Chapter 13 cases filed between 1980 and 1988); TERESA A. SULLIVAN, ELIZABETH WARREN,
& JAY LAWRENCE WESTBROOK, AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS; BANKRUPTCY AND CONSUMER
CREDIT IN AMERICA (1989). For additional details, see discussion infra, on dismissal and conversion.
Return to text
604 11 U.S.C. § 506 (1994).
Return to text
605 113 S. Ct. 2106 (1993).
Return to text
606 See, e.g., Wilson v. Commonwealth Mortgage Corp., 895 F.2d 123 (3d Cir. 1990); Hougland
v. Lomas & Nettleton Co., 886 F.2d 1182 (9th Cir. 1989); Hart v. Hart, 923 F.2d 1410 (10th Cir.
1991); Bellamy v. Federal Home Loan Mortgage Co., 962 F.2d 176 (2d Cir. 1992). See also Todd
Mason, Lenders Cringe As Judges Chop Mortgage Value, Wall St. J., Sept. 26, 1990. Liens
therefore were stripped but the interest rate and monthly payments remained the same, thus mortgage
lenders would receive the same regular monthly payments but for a shorter term. In addition, courts
formerly permitted Chapter 7 debtors to strip first mortgages until the Supreme Court deemed this
impermissible in Dewsnup v. Timm, 502 U.S. 410 (1992). Nobelman, 113 S.Ct. at 2110.
Return to text
607 11 U.S.C. § 1322, 1325 (1994).
Return to text
608 11 U.S.C. § 1322(b)(2) (1994). In re Johns, 37 F.3d 1021 (3d Cir. 1994) (if original
residential loan documents included additional security, loan not protected from modification,
regardless of subsequent foreclosure judgment that arguably extinguished security interest in
additional collateral); In re Hammon, 27 F.3d 52 (3rd Cir.1994) (debtor can bifurcate when creditor
has additional security); In re Libby, 200 B.R. 562 (Bankr. D.N.J. 1996) (mention of additional
security in loan documents eliminates antimodification protection even if additional security never
actually existed); In re Escue, 184 BR 287 (Bankr. M.D. Tenn. 1995) (inclusion of "refrigerator,
spare heater, and similar items," constituted additional security ). But see PNC Mortgage Co. v.
Dicks, 199 B.R. 674 (N.D. Ind. 1996) (majority of case law suggests that "boiler plate" interests not
additional security); accord In re Lievsay, 199 B.R. 705 (B.A.P. 9th Cir. 1996). Tax liens on homes,
which are not consensual security interests, may be subject to modification in Chapter 13. See, e.g.,
In re DeMaggio, 175 B.R. 144 (Bankr. D.N.H. 1994) (nonconsensual tax lien not consensual security
interest, not protected from modification in Chapter 13).
Return to text
609 Section 1322(c) provides: Notwithstanding subsection (b)(2) and applicable nonbankruptcy
law, (2) in a case in which the last payment on the original payment schedule for a claim secured only
by a security interest in real property that is the debtor's principal residence is due before the date on
which the final payment under the plan is due, the plan may provide for the payment of the claim as
modified pursuant to section 1325(a)(5) of this title. 11 U.S.C.§ 1322(c)(2) (1994); see also In re
Young, 199 B.R. 643, 646 (Bankr. E.D. Tenn. 1996) (plain meaning of new provision indicates that
plan may modify mortgage where payment becomes due during life of plan). Marianne B. Culhane,
Home Improvement? Home Mortgages and the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1994, 29 CREIGHTON L.
REV. 467, 490 (1996), 5 COLLIER ON BANKRUPTCY Ý 1322.14B (Lawrence P. King et al. eds. 15th ed.
1996). But see Witt v. United Companies Lending Corp., 113 F.3d 508 (4th Cir. 1997) (finding that
section 1322 (c)(2) is ambiguous and that legislative history implies that only payment schedule could
be modified and that claim could not be bifurcated).
Return to text
610 See, e.g., In re Purdue, 187 B.R. 188 (S. D. Ohio 1995); In re Geyer, 203 BR 726 (Bankr.
S.D. Cal. 1996); In re Vaillancourt, 197 B.R. 464 (Bankr. M.D. Pa. 1996); In re Hornes, 160 B.R.
709 (Bankr. D. Conn. 1993); In re Plouffe, 157 B.R. 198 (Bankr. D. Conn. 1993); In re Williams, 161
B.R. 27 (Bankr. E.D. Ky. 1993); In re Lee, 161 B.R. 271 (Bankr. W. D. Okla. 1993).
Return to text
611 Federal income tax laws, state property tax laws, the Federal Housing Administration, the
Community Reinvestment Act, Veteran's Administration loan guarantee programs, Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac, low income housing construction subsidies, mortgage securitization programs, and
financial institution regulations are just a sampling of the programs designed in part to facilitate
homeownership.
Return to text
612 Fewer than one percent of all institutions offered home equity loans and lines of credit in
1980, while 80% of banks and 65% of savings and loan institutions offered home equity loans in
1989. U.S. General Accounting Office, Tax Policy: Many Factors Contributed to the Growth of
Home Equity Financing in the 1980s, app. IV, 67 (1993). Consumer demand likely reacted to the
favorable tax treatment conferred on home equity borrowers, while attractive banking regulations
provided incentives to lenders to expand this area of lending. By 1991, second mortgages comprised
12% of home mortgage debt, having increased three-fold over the prior decade; this increase is
attributable mainly to growth in home equity lines of credit offerings. Id. at 9. Moreover, the
amount of mortgage debt outstanding grew three times faster than the value of homes in the same
period. Id. Loans grew from $1 billion in 1981 to $132 billion in 1991. Id. at 8, Table 1: Dollars
Outstanding and Growth Rates for Home Equity Financing, Id. at 8. Traditional second mortgages
increased from $59 to $225 billion in the same period. Id.
Return to text
613 See Francesca Eugeni, Consumer Debt and Home Equity Borrowing, Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 4 (Mar./Apr. 1993) (most of initial surge in home equity lending
from 1986 to 1988 occurred as customers were trying to take advantage of interest deductibility on
mortgage loans and were using home equity borrowing as substitute for other types of credit and as
source of funds to repay more expensive outstanding debt). Congress seriously considered but
rejected the elimination of this tax benefit for non-purchase money mortgages. See generally Julia
Patterson Forrester, Mortgaging the American Dream: A Critical Evaluation of the Federal
Government's Promotion of Home Equity Financing, 69 TUL. L. REV. 373 (1994).
Return to text
614 The Federal Reserve reported in February that consumers are compensating for the recent
slowdown in credit-card growth by taking out more home-equity loans, which have become more
easily attainable: 12.5% of the banks surveyed had eased terms for home equity loans in the fourth
quarter, while none tightened their standards. Home-Equity Loans Rise as Banks Tighten Credit-Card Terms, WALL ST. J., Feb. 11, 1997.
Return to text
615 Jeff Bailey, Consumer Loan Demand Remains Strong; Big Finance Companies Say Business
is Still Robust Despite Fears Over Debt. Wall St. J., Oct. 25, 1996, A2 (reporting that consumer
installment debt, adjusted to include car leases and home equity loans, has reached record high of
nearly 30% of disposable income).
Return to text
616 Less than 14% of homeowners in the general population had more than one mortgage on their
homes in 1991, American Housing Survey for the United States in 1991, Current Housing Reports
H150/91, Table 2-19, Income Costs, and Mortgage - Occupied Units (Washington: Bureau of the
Census 1993), as compared to the 27.2% of home owning debtors in bankruptcy that had more than
one mortgage at that same time, according to one empirical study. SULLIVAN, ETAL, FRAGILE MIDDLE CLASS,
(forthcoming) This percentage may be even higher; the constitution of one of the states comprising
the study, Texas, has disallowed second mortgages for more than 150 years. However, the Texas
legislature has recently revisited this question and the citizens of Texas will vote in early November
1997 on a constitutional amendment allowing home equity loans under limited circumstances. See
Proposed Constitutional Amendment -- Homestead Property -- Encumbrances; Joint Resolution,
1997 Tex. Sess. Law Serv. HS. Jt. Res. 31, (VERNON'S 1997). Lenders are gearing up for this new
lending opportunity. See Steve McLinden, Associates First Capital To Field Home-Equity Calls; The
Company Will Hire and Keep 230 Workers Even If State Voters Don't Approve the Lending Proposal
Nov. 4, FORT WORTH STAR-TELEGRAM, Oct. 3, 1997; Patrick Barta, Lenders Brace for Surge in
Home Loans, WALL ST. J., Aug. 20, 1997.
Return to text
617 Nancy Ann Jeffrey, Attention Shoppers: Get a Loan While Picking Up Groceries, Wall St.
J., Dec. 20, 1995.
Return to text
618 Carey Gillam, NationsBank Tries Ultra-High-Pressure Sales, 162 AM. BANKER, May 7, 1997,
at 6 (explaining that sales associates are expected to aim for selling nearly twenty loan products per
day, and announcing intent to mail home equity loan preapprovals to 1.2 million customers); Edward
Kulkosky, Pipeline Coming: Easier Pre-Approval of Equity Loans, 162 AM. BANKER, May 7, 1997,
at 9 (quoting consumer finance company saying that Americans have millions of home equity
waiting to be tapped). This may well be a conservative estimate, for others generally speculate that
the number is in the billions or trillions.
Return to text
619 See, e.g., Memorandum from Gary Klein Re: high rate/high cost loans (June 9, 1997)
(attaching high loan documentation for high percentage mortgages, with APRs ranging from 12.78 -
17.103%); Julia Patterson Forrester, Mortgaging the American Dream: A Critical Evaluation of the
Federal Government's Promotion of Home Equity Financing, 69 TUL. L. REV. 373, 376 (1994)
(family required by home equity lenders to pay off their existing installment land contract that carried
an 8% interest rate).
Return to text
620 "These Home-Equity Loans Could Endanger Your Financial Health," CHI. TRIB., May 21,
1997. See also Susan Pulliam, Big Banks Are Getting Roiled as They Follow 'Subprime Lenders' on
Easier Home Mortgages, WALL ST. J., Mar. 5, 1997, C2 (reporting that notwithstanding a 10% total
annual default rate, certain subprime lenders are predicted to generate as much as $3 billion in 1997
by charging interest rates exceeding 14.5 percent); Jeff Bailey, Lunchpail Lending; HFC Profits
Nicely By Charging Top Rates on some Risky Loans; Big Banks Join the Trend, But Consumer
Advocates Suspect 'Sucker Pricing, WALL ST. J., Dec. 11, 1996 (discussing how home equity loans
typically are marketed to consumers "already wallowing in debt," discussing typical non-bank lender
selling loans at over 15%).
Return to text
621 "Negative equity" home equity loans are becoming increasingly prevalent, even as first
mortgages. Susan Pulliam, Big Banks Are Getting Roiled as they Follow 'Subprime Lenders' on
Easier Home Mortgages, WALL ST. J., Mar. 5, 1997, C1 (explaining how Dan Marino, spokesperson
for one of these lenders, tells television audience, "you don't need any equity. All you need is a
phone").
Return to text
622 "Less than one-tenth of conventional mortgage loans had LTVs of greater than 90% at the start
of the decade. At their peak of popularity in mid-1995, 90% plus LTV loans were closing in on one-third of conventional mortgage loan originations. Mortgage loans equal to 125% of house values
have also become increasingly common." Mark M. Zandi, The Lender of First and Last Resort,
REGIONAL FIN. REV. at 3 (July 1997).
Return to text
623 Congress has legislated regarding high rate loans in other contexts. See Home Ownership and
Equity Protection Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1639 (1994).
Return to text
624 H.R. 6020 would have permitted stripdown of undersecured mortgages on the debtor's
personal residence, but would have limited stripdown of first mortgages to the extent they were
unsecured from the time the mortgage interest attached to the property. H.R. REP. NO. 102-996,
(1992). S. 1985, by contrast, would have permitted the modification of claims of junior mortgagees
that were partially unsecured when the interest attached, but the extent to which they could be
modified does not seem to be limited by the value at the time of attachment. S. 1985, 102nd Cong.,
(1992). The introduction of these bills preceded the Supreme Court's decision in Nobelman v.
American Savings Bank, 508 U.S. 324 (1993), which held that the Chapter 13 anti-modification
provision prevented mortgagee's claims from being bifurcated into secured and unsecured portions
pursuant to section 506.
Return to text
625 Federal National Mortgage Association, 1992 Annual Report 33 (1993); Federal Home Loan
Mortgage Corporation, 1992 Annual Report 55 (1993). Representatives of Freddie Mac confirm that
the percentage has not increased substantially since then. Likewise, the FHA and GNMA programs
deal predominantly with purchase money mortgages. A representative of Freddie Mac testified
before the Senate Judiciary Committee that "Freddie Mac's principal business is purchasing first
mortgages and also home improvement loans, although the home improvement loans are a much,
much smaller part of our portfolio and a much smaller part of our securities. Therefore, our primary
concern would be to extend the protection against cramdowns to first mortgages and also to home
improvement loans. With respect to other mortgages which may exist on the debtor's primary
residence, we really don't have a position as to that, and it really doesn't impact on our line of
business." Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Courts and Administrative Practice of the Committee
on the Judiciary, 102d Cong. (1991). Other associations' representatives who testified against
cramdown of undersecured mortgages at this hearing spoke almost exclusively in terms of first
mortgages.
Return to text
626 See Francesca Eugeni, Consumer Debt and Home Equity Borrowing, Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 7 (Mar./Apr. 1993) (securitization of home equity loans and lines
of credit has been growing at rapid pace since 1989). " In 1991, new issues of securities backed by
home equity loans and lines of credit reached an unprecedented $10 billion, with 37 percent of home
equity lines of credit securitized," which was estimated to grow to 42% in 1992. Id.
Return to text
627 See, e.g., Michael H. Schill, An Economic Analysis of Mortgagor Protection Laws, 77 VA.
L. REV. 489 (1991) (50-state empirical analysis of mortgage protection laws and mortgage rates).
Professor Schill has argued that, if anything, such mortgagor protection laws might promote economic
efficiency because they encourage lenders to value risk correctly. Id. See also Jane K. Winn, Lien
Stripping After Nobelman, 27 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 541, 587 (1994) (citing lack of data support for
repeated assertions of mortgage lenders that more generous lien stripping regime in bankruptcy will
have calamitous effects on availability of mortgage credit). "Mortgage insurance, not deficiency
liability, furnishes security for secondary market investors in shaky home mortgage markets." John
Mixon & Ira B. Shepard, Antideficiency Relief For Foreclosed Homeowners: ULSIA Section 511 (b),
27 WAKE FOREST L. REV. 455, 462 (1992). See also Philip Shuchman, Data on the Durrett
Controversy, 9 CARDOZO L. REV. 605 (1987) (no correlation between high borrowing rates and
greater consumer protection statutes).
Return to text
628 "If the rule supported herein was otherwise, to the extent that a secured creditor was paid more
than the real value of its lien, it would, in fact, be taking money from the limited pool of income
available for distribution to all unsecured creditors. A requirement that undersecured mortgage
creditors be paid in full would, in most cases, make it impossible to propose a feasible Chapter 13
plan to save a family home." See Position of the Commercial Law League of America, Hearing
Before the Subcommittee on Courts and Administrative Practice of the Committee on the Judiciary,
United States Senate, July 30, 1991.
Return to text
629 117 S.Ct. 1879 (1997).
Return to text
630 See 11 U.S.C. § 1325(a)(5)(B) (1994).
Return to text
631 "'Value' does not necessarily contemplate forced sale or liquidation value of collateral; nor
does it always imply a full going concern value. Courts will have to determine value on a case by
case basis, taking into account the facts of each case and the competing interests in the case." H.R.
REP. NO. 95-595 at 356 (1977), reprinted in 1978 U.S.C.C.A.N. 5787, 6312.
Return to text
632 See Stay Litigation After Rash, Our Two Cents,<http://www.stinson.com/2cents/rash.htm>
(which provides further delineation of potential valuation standards: "replacement cost (the current
cost of a similar item); fair market value (what a willing buyer would pay for a like item sold by a
willing seller); liquidation value (the estimated amount that could be realized from a forced sale of
the property at a public auction after proper advertising); orderly liquidation value (the amount that
could be realized from a forced sale of the property intact with all related equipment not necessarily
at an auction); retail value (the price for which an item is sold at retail); wholesale value (the price
for which an item is sold at wholesale); and going concern or enterprise value (the value of an
enterprise as a going concern, taking into account goodwill)." Letter from Elliot D. Levin, A
Proposal for the National Bankruptcy Review Commission: The Fair Distribution of Value Created
by the Bankruptcy Process Itself to the National Bankruptcy Review Commission (undated) (listing
various methods of valuation utilized: liquidation, fair value, fair market value, going concern value,
and cash value (when property is sold)).
Return to text
633 Cf. In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311 (7th Cir. 1996) (proper valuation was midpoint between
wholesale and retail); In re Rash, 90 F.3d 1036 (5th Cir. 1996) (en banc) (net foreclosure value),
rev'd, 117 S.Ct. 1879 (1997); Taffi v. United States, 96 F.3d 1190 (9th Cir. 1996) (en banc) (fair
market value for real property in individual Chapter 11 case), cert. denied, 117 S. Ct. 2748 (1997);
In re Trimble, 50 F.3d 530 (8th Cir. 1995) (retail value of vehicle without deduction for costs of sale).
See also In re Valenti, 105 F.3d 55, 62 (2nd Cir. 1997), (holding that it was within the bankruptcy
court's discretion to value at midpoint between wholesale and retail, but "no fixed value, whether it
be retail, wholesale, or some combination of the two, should be imposed on every bankruptcy court
conducting a § 506(a) valuation.").
Return to text
634 See Associates Commercial Corp. v. Rash, 90 F.3d 1036, 1060, 1062-63 (5th Cir. 1996) (en
banc), (majority and dissenting decisions reaching differing conclusions on number of circuit courts
that have held in favor of retail valuation), rev'd, 117 S.Ct. 1879 (1997).
Return to text
635 117 S. Ct. 1879 (1994).
Return to text
636 90 F.3d 1036, 1060 (5th Cir. 1996) (en banc), rev'd, 117 S.Ct. 1879 (1997).
Return to text
637 See, e.g., In re Inter-City Beverage Co., 209 B.R. 931 (Bankr. W.D. Mo. 1997) (applying
Supreme Court's Rash decision outside context of Chapter 13 cramdown to value property sold in
section 363 sale in Chapter 11 bankruptcy); In re Pepper, 210 B.R. 480 (Bankr. D. Col. 1997)
(applying Rash to Chapter 7 case in determining whether lien impaired exemption under section 522).
Return to text
638 "As Justice Stevens aptly points out in his dissent, section 506(a) is a 'utility' provision in that
applies throughout the various chapters of the Code. This interpretation of the value of the secured
claim also will apply to chapter 7, 11 and 12." Robert F. Mitch, The Rash Decision: A Question of
Value, AM. BANKR. INST. J., 18, 19 (July\Aug. 1997).
Return to text
639 See generally Chaim J. Fortgang & Thomas Moers Mayer, Valuation in Bankruptcy, 32 UCLA L. REV. 1061 (1985) (comprehensive review of valuation issues).
Return to text
640 The Supreme Court's decision in Rash potentially, although not definitively, calls into
question all section 506(a) opinions interpreting the appropriate valuation standard. Some of these
opinions are cited in this discussion not for their continuing precedential value, but rather to provide
context or for their philosophical bases.
Return to text
641 See Hon. Frank H. Easterbrook, Bankruptcy Reform, Luncheon Address to the National
Bankruptcy Review Commission Chicago Regional Hearing 4 (July 17, 1997) ("Replacement value
cannot be looked up. It must be litigated; and in the process the value of the asset will be paid out
to the lawyers rather than to the creditors.").
Return to text
642 See Letter from G. Ray Warner, regarding the need establish statutory guidelines, at 1 (July
30, 1997) (noting that Supreme Court left to each bankruptcy court the proper method of determining
value).
Return to text
643 See Robert F. Mitch, The Rash Decision: A Question of Value in Context, AM. BANKR. INST. J. 18, 19 (July/Aug. 1997).
Return to text
644 An estimate of value is not needed if the property is being sold. This is particularly true given
the Commission's Recommendation to clarify section 363(f) so that the value of the property is not
relevant to the decision to sell free and clear. See Chapter 2 - Business Bankruptcy.
Return to text
645 See In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 313201 (7th Cir. 1996) (Easterbrook, J. concurring)(advocating
that valuation rules be identical across chapters).
Return to text
646 See Letter from G. Ray Warner, regarding the need establish statutory guidelines, at 1 (July
30, 1997) (noting that Supreme Court left to each bankruptcy court the proper method of determining
value). See generally United Sav. Ass'n of Tex. v. Timbers of Inwood Forest Assoc., 484 U.S. 365,
371-72 (1988) (interpreting section 506(a) in considering creditors' entitlement to adequate protection
and determining that loss of right of immediate foreclosure is not factor to be considered in valuing
creditor's interest in collateral).
Return to text
647 "If a bankruptcy court assigns a liquidation value to the collateral of secured creditors, it
thereby awards the surplus to the unsecured creditors or to the debtor." David Gray Carlson, Car
Wars: Valuation Standards in Chapter 13 Bankruptcy Cases, 13 BANKR. DEV. J. 1, 2 (1996).
Return to text
648 Rash, 117 S.Ct. at 1887 (Stevens, J. dissenting)("Allowing any more than the foreclosure
value simply grants a general windfall to undersecured creditors at the expense of unsecured
creditors); In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311 (7th Cir. 1996) (Easterbrook, J. concurring) (noting that retail
valuation does not result in unjustified wealth transfer to debtors because valuation standard in
Chapter 13, like Chapter 11, implicates only "relative stakes of secured and unsecured debts"). See
also David Gray Carlson, Secured Creditors and the Eely Character of Bankruptcy Valuations, 41
AM. U. L. REV. 63, 79 (1991) (choice of determinative price depends on whether one believes that
secured creditors or general creditors should receive the bonus associated with going concern; "logic
alone cannot settle such questions in an uncontroversial manner").
Return to text
649 "Wholesale and retail values can be looked up in tables. They are simple to administer and
satisfy my test for a good rule."See Hon. Frank H. Easterbrook, Bankruptcy Reform, Luncheon
Address to the National Bankruptcy Review Commission Chicago Regional Hearing 4 (July 17,
1997)
Return to text
650 In re Marshall, 181 B.R. 599, 604 n.9 (Bankr. N.D. Ala. 1995) (NADA publication universally
recognized as relevant and material evidence of value of used cars); In re Johnson, 165 B.R. 524, 529
(S.D. Ga. 1994) (NADA values are widely used in auto industry and courts to simplify and expedite
valuation process); In re Wierschem, 152 B.R. 345, 347 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 1993) (taking judicial
notice of the NADA values).
Return to text
651 See, e.g., Hon. Edith H. Jones, Recommendations for Reform of Consumer Bankruptcy Law
18 (Aug. 6, 1997 draft) (recommending adoption of simple standard for valuing collateral).
Return to text
652 See Hon. Frank H. Easterbrook, Bankruptcy Reform, Luncheon Address to the National
Bankruptcy Review Commission Chicago Regional Hearing 5 (July 17, 1997) Examples of such
costs offered by the Supreme Court included warranties, inventory, storage, reconditioning, and costs
associated with modifications to the property that would not be subject to the creditor's lien under
state law. Rash, 117 S. Ct. at 1886, n.6.
Return to text
653 In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311 (7th Cir. 1996) (adopting midpoint valuation); In re Valenti 105
F.3d 55 (2nd Cir. 1997) (bankruptcy court did not err by upholding midpoint valuation).
Return to text
654 Forced sale value should not be equated with wholesale value. In re Taffi, 68 F.3d 306, 308
(9th Cir. 1995), aff'd en banc, 96 F.3d 1190 (9th Cir. 1996). "Such sales are notoriously poor in
producing cash proceeds." David Gray Carlson, Car Wars: Valuation Standards in Chapter 13
Bankruptcy Cases, 13 BANKR. DEV. J. 1, 2 (1996). Forced sale prices tend not to adequately value
property, and the failure to obtain the best price for collateral does not, by itself, permit a sale to be
set aside as commercially unreasonable. U.C.C. § 9-507(2); see, e.g., Chavers v. Frazier, 93 B.R. 366
(Bankr. M.D. Tenn. 1989) (airplane that was insured for $700,000 sold at Article 9 sale for
$415,000). "The overlooked problem, of course is that 'retail' and 'wholesale' blue book prices have
never been proxies for 'replacement' and 'forced sale' values. Wholesale value has never represented
the amount that a creditor recovers after repossession and resale. Similarly, retail value has little to
do with what a consumer would have to pay to buy a replacement automobile of like condition
without a warranty from another consumer." Gary Klein, Opinion Raises More Questions Than it
Answers, AM. BANKR. INST. J. 18 (July/Aug. 1997).
Return to text
655 Alvin C. Harrell, UCC Article 9 Drafting Committee Considers October 1996 Draft, 51
CONSUMER FINANCE L. Q. REP. (1997) (reporting that committee met to discuss low price foreclosure
sales, among other issues); Donald J. Rapson, Efficient Treatment of Deficiency Claims: Gilmore
Would have Repented, 75 WASH. U.L.Q. 491 (1997) (urging adoption of rule deal with prevalent
tendency for secured parties to bid on collateral in foreclosure sales for far less than fair market value
and then collect significant deficiency judgment). "[T]here is a positive incentive for [secured
creditor] to buy at below the fair foreclosure value of the collateral. In all three cases, the actual
"price" paid at the foreclosure sale is economically irrelevant to them except as it fixes the amount
of deficiency. The lower the foreclosure sales price paid, the larger the deficiency which may be
recovered from the debtor. And there is an opportunity for the secured party, recourse party, or related
party to sell the collateral at a price which nets them more, sometimes substantially more, than the
price they bid at the foreclosure sale." Gail hildebrand, The Uniform Commercial Code Drafting
Process: Will Articles 2, 2B, and 9 Be Fair to Consumers?, 75 WASH. U.L.Q. 69, 133, 137 (1997)
(noting continual problem of sales yielding values at far less than market price, citing studies of low
disposition prices in consumer sales), citing David B. McMahon, Commercially Reasonable Sales
and Deficiency Judgments Under UCC Article 9: An Analysis of Revision Proposals, 48 CONSUMER
FIN. L.J. REP. 64 (1994); Armstrong v. Csurilla, 817 P.2d 1221 (N.M. 1991) (discussing low prices
that foreclosure sales often bring and when they can be deemed inadequate). "[T]he only bidder at
99% of foreclosure sales is the mortgagee . . . State foreclosure laws have failed to adequately protect
the debtor from low sales prices. The statutory notice requirements generate little interest and most
mortgagees have little incentive to advertise." Robert Burford, Can Mortgage Foreclosure Sales
Really be Fraudulent Conveyances Under Section 548(a)(2) of the Bankruptcy Code?, 22 HOUS. L.
REV. 1221, 1248 (1985). Lynn M. LoPucki, A General Theory of the Dynamics of the State
Remedies/Bankruptcy System, 1982 WIS. L. REV. 311, 320-21, n.52 (sales procedures used by
bankruptcy courts are "vastly superior to those employed in the state remedies subsystem"). But see
Rash, 90 F.3d at 1052, n.20 (secured creditor presented testimony that it regularly received 92% of
retail price for its trucks at foreclosure sales).
Return to text
656 In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311 (7th Cir. 1996) (average of wholesale and retail value).
Return to text
657 Id. at 315 (people who find themselves in a bilateral monopoly situation will often agree
simply to split the difference).
Return to text
658 See, e.g., In re Valenti, 105 F.3d 55, 58 (2d Cir. 1997) (considering N.D.N.Y Local Bankr.
R.); In re Sharon, 200 B.R. 181, 195 (Bankr. S.D. Ohio 1996).
Return to text
659 Butner v. United States, 440 U.S. 48 (1979); In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311 (7th Cir. 1996)
(Easterbrook, J. concurring). Associates Commercial Corp. v. Rash, 90 F.3d 1036, 1042, (5th Cir.
1996) (en banc) (if creditor is entitled to replacement cost, would modify extent to which creditor is
secured under state law), rev'd on other grounds, 117 S. Ct. 1879 (1997).
Return to text
660 U.C.C. §§ 9-502 - 9-505.
Return to text
661 Rash, 90 F.3d at 1042, rev'd., 117 S. Ct. 1879 (1997); In re Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311
(Easterbrook, J. concurring). "If the debtor must pay the secured creditor the retail value of the
collateral in order to retain the collateral under Section 1325(a)(5)(B), the apparent congruence of
protection afforded by Sections 1325(a)(5)(B) and (C) [providing option to surrender collateral]
would be lost." In re Maddox, 200 B.R. 546, 553 (D.N.J. 1996) (affirming bankruptcy court's
application of wholesale value to vehicles to be retained in Chapter 13).
Return to text
662 S. Andrew Bowman & William M. Thompson, Secured Claims Under Section 1325(a)(5)(B):
Collateral Valuation, Present Value, and Adequate Protection, 15 IND. L. REV. 569. 577 (1982),
cited in Rash, 90 F.3d at 1047, rev'd, 117 S. Ct. 1879 (1997). "A debtor may cram down a plan either
by abandoning the collateral to the secured party (so that a foreclosure sale can occur under state law),
or by retaining the collateral but distributing legal rights with a comparable value to the secured
creditor. These two cram down options should be the same, from the perspective of the secured
creditor." David Gray Carlson, Car Wars: Valuation Standards in Chapter 13 Bankruptcy Cases, 13
BANKR. DEV. J. 1, 8-9 (1996).
Return to text
663 "[T]he highest valuing user enjoys the rest of the value as consumer surplus. . . That is what
bankruptcy valuation is supposed to replicate, and the use of wholesale price does the job." In re
Hoskins, 102 F.3d 311, 320 (7th Cir. 1996) (Easterbrook, J. concurring).
Return to text
664 "The distinction between wholesale and retail prices is a false one. Retail prices reflect value
added by the retailer. If the cost of value added by the retailer were to be removed from retail value,
the remainder would be wholesale value. Hence, wholesale is simply retail minus the transaction costs
of retailing . . .these transaction costs ought to be removed. David Gray Carlson, Car Wars: Valuation
Standards in Chapter 13 Bankruptcy Cases, 13 BANKR. DEV. J. 1, 8 (1996) "The retailer adds value
to the transaction. The retailer maintains an inventory of automobiles, reducing the number of sites
a buyer must visit to complete a transaction and thereby reducing the buyer's search costs. The
retailer, like the securities dealer, also stands ready to buy and sell automobiles, thereby providing
liquidity to the marketplace. A retailer also may provide explicit or implicit certifications of quality,
perhaps through the retailer's reputation in the community." Robert M. Lawless & Stephen P. Ferris,
Economics and the Rhetoric of Valuation, 5 J. BANKR. L. & P. 3, 16-18 (1995) ("We believe that a
value that approximates wholesale price should be the relevant measure of [lender]'s claim for
purposes of the Chapter 13 cramdown . . . Because the value of an automobile sold in the market at
the wholesale level comes almost directly from the manufacturing activities of the dealer, the
wholesale price of the automobile likely comes closest to representing the automobile's true worth").
Return to text
665 This standard would not apply to mortgages on the primary residence of a Chapter 11 or 13 debtor retaining the residence when such mortgages are protected from modification. This standard
presumably would apply, however, to personal property forms of holding real property, such as land
trusts.
Return to text
666 See, e.g., Taffi v. United States, 96 F.3d 1190 (9th Cir. 1996) (en banc), cert. denied, 117 S.
Ct. 2748 (1997); In re Trimble, 50 F.3d 530 (8th Cir. 1995); Winthrop Old Farm Nurseries v. New
Bedford Institution for Savings, 50 F.3d 72 (1st Cir. 1995); In re McClurkin, 31 F.3d 401, 405 (6th
Cir.1994). Cf. In re Balbus, 933 F.2d 246, 250-52 (4th Cir.1991) (where purpose of valuation was
to determine whether debtor had too much unsecured credit to qualify as Chapter 13 debtor, and
where debtor would retain house under plan, value of creditor's interest in house was amount creditor
would receive at foreclosure sale).
Return to text
667 See, e.g., Bank of Am., Ill. v. 203 N. LaSalle St. Partnership, 195 B.R. 692 (N.D. Ill. 1996)
(valuing real property at its fair market value but deducting disposition costs), aff'g, 190 B.R. 567
(Bankr. N.D. Ill. 1995), aff'd, No. 96-2137 & 96-2138 (slip. op.) (7th Cir. Sept. 29, 1996).
Return to text
668 The Supreme Court held in BFP v. Resolution Trust Corp., 511 U.S. 53 (1994) that a noncollusive foreclosure sale price would be reasonably equivalent value for purposes of determining
whether the sale was a fraudulent conveyance. However, reasonably equivalent value does not equate
with fair market value.
Return to text
669 See Butner v. United States, 440 U.S. 48 (1979).
Return to text
670 David Gray Carlson, Car Wars: Valuation Standards in Chapter 13 Bankruptcy Cases, 13 BANKR. DEV. J. 1, 51 (1996).
Return to text
671 Associates Commercial Corp. v. Rash, 31, F.3d 325 (5th Cir. 1994), rev'd on rehearing en banc, 90 F.3d 1036 (1996), rev'd, 117 S. Ct. 1879 (1997).
Return to text
672 Robert M. Lawless & Stephen P. Ferris, Economics and the Rhetoric of Valuation, 5 J. BANKR. L. & PRAC. 3, 18 (1995) (consumer debtor, as one-time dealer, cannot provide services to
marketplace that would permit her to charge higher retail price).
Return to text
673 Id. at 5.
Return to text
674 H.R. 1085, 98th Cong., 1st Sess. § 19(2)(A) (1983); H.R. 1169, 98th Cong., 1st Sess. §
19(2)(A) (1983); H.R. 4786, 97th Cong., § 19(2)(A) (1981). See generally Key Bank of N.Y. v.
Harko, 211 B.R. 116 n.7 (B.A.P.2nd Cir. 1997).
Return to text
675 See, e.g., Green Tree Fin. Serv. Corp. v. Smithwick,121 F.3d 211 (5th Cir. 1997) (reversing
and remanding bankruptcy court application of interest rate by local rule and holding that contract
interest rate is presumptively appropriate cramdown rate unless debtor comes forward with evidence
showing that creditor's current rate is less); General Motors Acceptance Corp. v. Jones, 999 F.2d 63,
65 (3d Cir. 1993).
Return to text
676 United Carolina Bank v. Hall, 993 F.2d 1126, 1130-31 (4th Cir. 1993) (match rate of return
to secured creditor with what creditor otherwise would obtain in its lending market); In re Hardzog,
901 F.2d 858, 860 (10th Cir. 1990) (in Chapter 12 case, market of similar loans in the area utilized);
Memphis Bank and Trust Co., v. Whitman, 692 F.2d 427, 431 (6th Cir. 1982) (same).
Return to text
677 See, e.g., Green Tree Fin. Serv. Corp. v. Smithwick,121 F.3d 211 (5th Cir. 1997); General Motors Acceptance Corp. v. Jones, 999 F.2d 63, 65 (3d Cir. 1993).
Return to text
678 See United Carolina Bank v. Hall, 993 F.2d at 1130; United States v. Doud, 869 F.2d 1144, 1145-46 (8th Cir. 1989); Koopmans v. Farm Credit Servs., 196 B.R. 425, 427 (N.D. Ind.), aff'd, 102 F.3d 874 (7th Cir. 1996).
Return to text
679 See, e.g., In re Hudock, 124 B.R. 532, 534 (Bankr. N.D. Ill. 1991) ("The Bankruptcy Code protects the creditor's interest in the property, not the creditor's interest in the profit it had hoped to make on the loan."); In re Cellular Info. Sys., Inc., 171 B.R. 926, 939 (Bankr. S.D.N.Y. 1994); see
generally Todd J. Zywicki, Cramdown and the Code: Calculating Cramdown Interest Rates Under
the Bankruptcy Code, 19 THUR. MARSH. L. REV. 241 (1994).
Return to text
680 Shearson Lehman Mortgage Corp. v. Laguna, 944 F.2d 542 (9th Cir. 1991), cert. denied, 503 U.S. 966 (1992).
Return to text
681 "This method of calculating interest is preferable to either the "cost of funds" approach or the
"forced loan" approach because it is easy to apply, it is objective, and it will lead to uniform results.
In addition, the treasury rate is responsive to market conditions." In re Valenti, 105 F.3d 55, 64 (2d
Cir. 1997) (reversing lower court determination that 9% market rate applied to cramdown interest
payments), citing Heartland Fed. Sav. & Loan Ass'n v. Briscoe Enters., 994 F.2d 1160, 1169 (5th Cir.
1993); Doud, 869 F.2d at 1145-46; In re Dingley, 189 B.R. at 271; In re Smith, 178 B.R. at 953; In
re Wynnefield Manor Assocs., L.P., 163 B.R. 53, 60 (Bankr. E.D. Pa. 1993).
Return to text
682 Valenti, 105 F.3d at 55, citing Farm Credit Bank v. Fowler (In re Fowler), 903 F.2d 694, 697-98 (9th Cir. 1990); Koopmans v. Farm Credit Servs., 196 B.R. 425, 427 (N.D. Ind.), aff'd, 102 F.3d 874 (7th Cir. 1996); In re Dingley, 189 B.R. at 271 (citations omitted); In re Cellular, 171 B.R. at 940.
Return to text
683 113 S. Ct. 2187 (1993).
Return to text
684 140 CONG. REC. H10,769 (daily ed. Oct. 4, 1994).
Return to text
685 General Motors Acceptance Corp. v. Jones, 999 F.2d 63, 65 (3d Cir. 1993).
Return to text
686 11 U.S.C. § 1325(b) (1994).
Return to text
687 Bankruptcy Amendments and Judgeship Act of 1984, Pub. L. No. 98-353, 98 Stat. 333 (1984).
Return to text
688 See Kathleen A. Laughlin, A Chapter 13 Trustee's Guidelines for Determining Disposable
Income: A Task that Would Give a Woodpecker a Headache! 6 NAT'L ASS'N CH. 13 TRUSTEES Q.
13 (Jan. 1994). See also Comment, Reasonably Necessary Expenses or Life of Riley? The Disposable
Income Test and Chapter 13 Debtor's Lifestyle, 56 MO. L. REV. 617, 632 (1992).
Return to text
689 In re Jones, 55 B.R. 462, 466-67 (Bankr. D. Minn. 1985) (private school tuition
objectionable).
Return to text
690 See, e.g., In re Gonzales, 157 B.R. 604, 607-09 (Bankr. E.D. Mich. 1993) (finding educational
expenses for masters program discretionary and thus not reasonably necessary); In re Jones, 55
Bankr. 462, 466-67 (Bankr. D. Minn. 1985) (college tuition payments objectionable); In re Jolly, 13
B.R 123, 125 (Bankr. E.D. Wis. 1981) (pre-disposable income case holding under good faith standard
that money saved for children's education should be available to creditors).
Return to text
691 See, e.g., In re Fields, 190 B.R. 16, 18-19 (Bankr. D.N.H. 1995) (confirming discretionary
expenses for family of five of $145 per month to cover cost of newspapers, birthday presents, and
other discretionary items).
Return to text
692 Compare In re Tessier, 190 B.R. 396, 403 (Bankr. D. Mont. 1995) (plan not confirmable
because tithing not reasonably necessary, so falls within disposable income) with In re Bien, 95 B.R.
281, 282 (Bankr. D. Conn. 1989) (tithe was reasonably necessary expenditure); In re Cavanagh, 175
B.R. 369, 374-75 (Bankr. D. Idaho 1994) (tithing not reasonably necessary, but within discretionary
spending); In re Green, 73 B.R. 893, 893 (Bankr. W.D. Mich. 1987) (court would violate First
Amendment by denying confirmation of Chapter 13 plan based on declared intention to make tithing
to church), aff'd, 103 B.R. 852 (W.D. Mich. 1988); In re McDaniel, 126 B.R. 782 (Bankr. D. Minn.
1991) (finding a proposed monthly tithe of $540.00 excessive). See generally Note, Tithing in
Chapter 13 - A Divine Creditor Exception To Section 1325? 110 HARV. L. REV. 1125, 1142 (1997)
(Establishment Clause mandates refusal to recognize tithing; "were the bankruptcy courts to shift
course by exempting tithes from the section 1325(b) disposable-income test, they would
impermissibly favor religious interests over nonreligious interests"). But see Carol Koenig, To Tithe
or Not to Tithe: The Constitutionality of Tithing in a Chapter 13 Bankruptcy Budget, 32 SANTA
CLARA L. REV. 1231, 1252-57 (1992); Bruce E. Kosub & Susan K. Thompson, The Religious
Debtor's Conviction to Tithe as the Price of a Chapter 13 Discharge, 66 TEX. L. REV. 873, 892-903
(1988); Oliver B. Pollak, Be Just Before You're Generous: Tithing and Charitable Contributions in
Bankruptcy, 29 CREIGHTON L. REV. 527, 575 (1996); Donald R. Price & Mark C. Rahdert,
Distributing the First Fruits: Statutory and Constitutional Implications of Tithing in Bankruptcy, 26
U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 853, 855, 901-16 (1993); Aric D. Martin, Chapter 13 and the Tithe: Is God a
Creditor?, 56 OHIO ST. L.J. 307, 322-25 (1995). See also Chapter 13 Trustee District of Nebraska
Budgetary Guidelines, 6 NAT'L ASS'N CH. 13 TRUSTEES Q. 16 (1994) (listing charitable contributions
as specific expense item in budget guidelines). The Religious Liberty and Charitable Donation
Protection Act of 1997, S. Bill 1244, introduced on October 1, 1997, expressly would amend section
1325 to include some charitable contributions in reasonably necessary expenses. A companion bill,
H.R. 2604, was introduced on October 2, 1997.
Return to text
693 See, e.g., In re Sutliff, 79 B.R. 151, 156 (Bankr. N.D.N.Y. 1987) ("an inquiry into a debtor's
'reasonably necessary' expenses is unavoidably a judgment of values and lifestyles and close
questions emerge."); In re Rogers, 65 B.R. 1018, 1021 (Bankr. E.D. Mich. 1986) ("This question
unavoidably involves the bankruptcy court in difficult value judgments.... It's an unpleasant job, but
someone has to do it"); KEITH LUNDIN, 1 CHAPTER 13 BANKRUPTCY § 531, 5-98l-99 (Wiley Law
Publications, 1992) ("Determining reasonable necessary expenses drags the bankruptcy court into
approving or disapproving of the debtor's lifestyle"); Karen Gross, Preserving A Fresh Start For the
Individual Debtor: The Case for Narrow Construction of the Consumer Credit Amendments, 135 U.
PA. L. REV. 59 (1986).
Return to text
694 This issue was discussed at length at the Commission's consumer bankruptcy working group brainstorming session in Dallas, Texas on April 5, 1997.
Return to text
695 See Kathleen A. Laughlin, A Chapter 13 Trustee's Guidelines for Determining Disposable
Income: A Task that Would Give a Woodpecker a Headache! 6 NAT'L ASS'N CH. 13 TRUSTEES Q.
13 (Jan. 1994) (describing problems and attaching guidelines on reasonably necessary expenses for
District of Nebraska); see also Affidavit of Arnold H. Wurhman, Staff Attorney in office of Amrane
Cohen, Chapter 13 Trustee in the Central District of California (May 7, 1997) (delineating
procedures for his preparation of table of monthly average income and expenditures based on
consumer expenditure survey of U.S. Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics and Consumer
Price Index-All Urban Consumers for Los Angeles-Long Beach area). See generally Letter from
Kathleen A. McDonald, President, National Association of Chapter 13 Trustees regarding Consumer
Bankruptcy Working Group Proposals, (June 11, 1997) (commenting that most trustees have written
or unwritten templates and attaching some examples).
Return to text
696 See Jean Braucher, Lawyers and Consumer Bankruptcy: One Code, Many Cultures, 67 AM.
BANKR. L.J. 501, 532 (1993) (explaining practice of some lawyers of computing plan payment
necessary to pay debts including required percentage of debt and working backward to derive budget,
leading to inaccuracies).
Return to text
697 See Jean Braucher, Counseling Consumer Debtors To Make their Own Informed Choices- A
Question of Professional Responsibility, 5 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 165, 183 (1997) (stating that
listing all possible budget items will help debtor identify expenses and plan accordingly, but court
may refuse certain of these items as luxuries and not reasonably necessary, thus noting that it may not
be advisable to actually list items on schedules).
Return to text
698 Statement of Hon. Robert Ginsberg, Transcript from February 20, 21, 1997 Meeting. See also
Letter from Hon. Edith Jones, regarding consumer bankruptcy (July 15, 1997) (attaching court order
from U.S. Bankruptcy Court for the Southern District of Texas describing how "bankruptcy mill
practitioner was able to run an efficient shop. He and his paralegals made up the debtors' expense
statements so that they would not reflect much disposable income.").
Return to text
699 11 U.S.C. § 1325(a)(3) (1994).
Return to text
700 See, e.g., In re Greer, 60 B.R. 547 (Bankr. C.D. Cal. 1986) (zero-repayment plans legally
permissible); Hon. C. Michael Stilson, U.S. Bankruptcy Judge, Northern District of Alabama,
Comments on the National Bankruptcy Review Commission Consumer Bankruptcy Working Group's
May 6, 1997 Draft, at 3 (June 6, 1997)(predetermined percentage requirements is contrary to language
of Bankruptcy Code). An informal survey of the judges in the Seventh Circuit revealed that of 24
judges responding, 13 sometimes confirmed zero percent payment plans and 11 never confirmed zero
percent payment plans. Letter from Hon. Russell Eisenberg to Elizabeth Warren, (December 14,
1992) (attaching Chapter 13 Questionnaire of Bankruptcy Judges in the Seventh Circuit). See
William C. Whitford, Has the Time Come to Repeal Chapter 13? 65 Ind. L. J. 85, 97 n.39 (1989)
(practitioners often assume that debtors should not file zero or low percentage repayment plans
because they are burdensome on Chapter 13 trustees and because they believe certain bankruptcy
courts will not approve the plans).
Return to text
701 See Teresa A. Sullivan, Elizabeth Warren & Jay Lawrence Westbrook, The Persistence of
Local Legal Culture: Twenty Years of Evidence from the Federal Bankruptcy Courts, 17 HARV. J.
L. & PUB. POL. 801, 833 (1994) (results of empirical study show that courts and trustees in various
districts have different expectations of percentage of unsecured debt that must be pledged in Chapter
13 repayment plans).
Return to text
702 11 U.S.C. § 1325(a)(4), (5) (1994).
Return to text
703 See Letter from Robert R. Weed (June 15, 1997).
Return to text
704 See, e.g, Hon. Marilyn Morgan, U.S. Bankr. Judge, Northern District of California, Comments
for the National Bankruptcy Review Commission (May 14, 1997) (stating that she could not imagine
a standardized disposable income approach that will encompass diversity in Chapter 13 cases); Karen
Gross, Preserving A Fresh Start For the Individual Debtor: The Case for Narrow Construction of
the Consumer Credit Amendments, 135 U. PA. L. REV. 59 (1986).
Return to text
705 See H.R. 2500, Section by Section Analysis Title I, § 102. "Adequate Income Shall Be Committed to a Plan that Pays Unsecured Creditors" (Issued by Rep. McCollum, Sept. 17, 1997).
Return to text
706 See In re Kelly, 841 F.2d 908, 915 (9th Cir. 1988) (excess monthly income of $440 not
reasonably necessary for support and excessive recreation expenses warranted dismissal), citing In
re Hudson, 56 B.R. 415, 419 (Bankr. N.D. Ohio 1985) (debtor's ability to pay debts when due is
substantial abuse of Chapter 7); In re Huckfeldt, 39 F.3d 829 (8th Cir. 1994); Fonder v. United
States, 974 F.2d 996 (8th Cir. 1992) (debtor able to pay 89% of debts in three years); In re Walton,
866 F.2d 981 (8th Cir. 1989) (could pay two-thirds of debt in three years), aff'd, 866 F.2d 981 (8th
Cir. 1989); Stuart v. Koch, 109 F.3d 1285 (8th Cir. 1997).
Return to text
707 See, e.g., In re Zaleta, 211 B.R. 178 (Bankr. M.D. 1997) (Chapter 7 case not substantial abuse
because debtor not able to pay all debts in reasonable time).
Return to text
708 In re Krohn, 886 F.2d 123, 126 (6th Cir. 1989). See also Ontiveros, 198 B.R. 284, 288 (D.
Ill. 1996).
Return to text
709 In re Green, 934 F.2d 568, 572 (4th Cir. 1991); see also Balaja, 190 B.R. 335, 338 (Bankr.
N.D. Ill. 1996) (arguing that per se rule of Eighth and Ninth Circuits would give no effect to clearly
stated statutory presumption in favor of granting relief to debtor).
Return to text
710 Green, 934 F.2d at 572; see also In re Kestell, 99 F.3d 146, 149 (4th Cir. 1996) (debtor
attempted to substantially abuse bankruptcy system by seeking to avoid paying ex-wife while
reaffirming all debts to other creditors and failing to disclose all assets); In re Shands, 63 B.R. 121,
124 (Bankr. E.D. Mich. 1985) (same); In re Deaton, 65 B.R. 663, 665 (Bankr. S.D. Ohio 1986); In
re Keniston, 95 B.R. 202 (Bankr. D. N.H. 1988) (ability to pay debts without additional factors
amounting to bad faith was not substantial abuse).
Return to text
711 See In re Haffner, 198 B.R. 646, 649 (Bankr. D. R.I. 1996) (reducing expenses attributable
to "900 number" calls made by nondebtor spouse's son from prior marriage, determining that case
should be dismissed for substantial abuse); In re Dickerson, 193 B.R. 67, 68 (Bankr. M.D. Fla. 1996)
(going through details of debtor's medical operation and resulting expenses in great mathematical
detail, determining that case was not substantial abuse because there was at least a $400/month
deficit). A judge may be inclined to investigate the income and expenses of a nondebtor spouse as
well. Cf. In re Haffner, 198 B.R. at 649 (declining to include nondebtor's income, but also refusing
to include expenses that court found attributable to nondebtor spouse's child from prior marriage),
with In re Strong, 84 B.R. 541 (Bankr. N.D. Ill. 1988) (including nondebtor spouse's annual income
of $38,000 in substantial abuse analysis).
Return to text
712 KEITH M. LUNDIN, CHAPTER 13 BANKRUPTCY, § 7.31 (2d ed. 1994) (noting that the method
of payment of chapter 13 attorneys fees has been litigated and varies widely).
Return to text
713 See, e.g., In re Shorb, 101 B.R. 185 (B.A.P 9th Cir. 1989) (chapter 13 debtor's attorney fees
must be paid before or contemporaneously with other claims, reversing bankruptcy court order
providing that attorney's fees not be paid until 6 months after commencement of payments to
unsecured creditors); see, e.g., In re Tenney, 63 B.R. 110 (Bankr. W.D. Okla. 1986) (approving
chapter 13 plan paying administrative expenses in full before secured claims) In re Cason, 190 B.R.
917 (Bankr. N.D. Ala. 1995) (attorney's fees, like administrative expenses, must be paid before or
at same time as other claims). This case also notes that the Bankruptcy Court for the
Northern District of Alabama has adopted a "Memorandum On Compensation in Chapter 13 Cases."
Pursuant to the Memorandum, debtors attorneys will receive an initial distribution and subsequent
monthly payments as an administrative expense by the standing trustee. The amount paid to the
debtor's attorney depends on the amount of claims paid by the standing trustee.
Return to text
714 See, e.g., In re Lanigan, 101 B.R. 530 (Bankr. N.D. Ill. 1986) (court authorized to spread
payment over life of plan, and approving attorney fees spread out over number of months).
Return to text
715 See, e.g, In re Parker, 15 B.R. 980 (Bankr. E.D. Tenn. 1981), aff'd, 21 B.R. 692 (E.D. Tenn.
1982) (administrative expenses may be paid concurrently with payments to other claim holders); See
Bankruptcy Court for the Northern District of California, Oakland Division, Standing
Order: "Rights and Responsibilities of Chapter 13 Debtors and their Attorneys," (June 1, 1994)
(providing that attorneys get paid through plan unless otherwise ordered; "attorney may not receive
fees directly from the debtor other than the initial retainer").
Return to text
716 In re Lanigan, 101 B.R. 530 (Bankr. N.D. Ill.1986) (spreading out payments will make attorney pay more attention to the proposed plan so that attorney shares risk of potential plan failure).
Return to text
717 Letter from Melvin James Kaplan, Chicago, IL to Melissa Jacoby (June 26, 1997); See also
memorandum from Jean Braucher, regarding Comments on June 10, 1997 Draft Proposals
Concerning Consumer Bankruptcy 2 (July 8, 1997).
Return to text
718 11 U.S.C. § 1329 (1994) (party can request modification to increase or reduce payments,
extend or reduce time for payments, or alter amount of distribution to creditor).
Return to text
719 11 U.S.C. § 1307(a) (1994) (debtor may convert to Chapter 7 at any time, and any waiver of
right to convert is unenforceable).
Return to text
720 11 U.S.C. § 1328(b) (1994) (after notice and hearing, court may grant discharge in spite of
noncompletion if debtor's failure to complete payments is due to circumstances for which debtor
should not be held accountable, if value actually distributed is not less than amount creditors would
have received in Chapter 7, and modification under section 1329 is not practicable).
Return to text
721 11 U.S.C. § 1307(b) (1994) (debtor has right to seek dismissal at any time), § 1307(c)
(grounds for converting or dismissing, including unreasonable delay or material default under plan).
Return to text
722 See Electronic Mail from Derek M. Shirk regarding comment that "many debtors select 7 over 13 because of the risk that they will not receive a discharge in 13"(May 26, 1997).
Return to text
723 11 U.S.C. § 1307(a) (1994).
Return to text
724 Michael Bork and Susan D. Tuck, Administrative Office of the U.S. Courts Bankruptcy
Statistical Trends; Chapter 13; Dispositions (Working Paper 2) (October 1994) (studying termination
data for Chapter 13 cases filed between 1980 and 1988).
Return to text
725 Id.; see also TERESA A. SULLIVAN, ELIZABETH WARREN & JAY LAWRENCE WESTBROOK, AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS; BANKRUPTCY AND CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA (Oxford Univ. Press
1989) (of 481 Chapter 13 cases in sample, 107 already had been dismissed at time of writing, whereas
only 48 had been converted to Chapter 7).
Return to text
726 See ABI Consumer Bankruptcy Reform Forum Summary and Report on Options (Not dated), which can be found in the Appendix.
Return to text
727 See Visa, U.S.A., Inc. Preliminary Report, Consumer Bankruptcy, Bankruptcy Debtor Survey
(April 1997) (of "more than 3,500" former Chapter 7 and 13 debtors responding, 8.6% stated that they
had filed 2 cases and 2.5% reported to have filed three or more cases); TERESA A. SULLIVAN,
ELIZABETH WARREN & JAY LAWRENCE WESTBROOK, AS WE FORGIVE OUR DEBTORS; BANKRUPTCY
AND CONSUMER CREDIT IN AMERICA(1989) (about 8% of debtors in sample of 1502 petitions had
been debtors previously).
Return to text
728 Susan L. DeJarnatt, Empirical Study-Chapter 13 Repeat Filings; Preliminary Analysis, Draft (September 11, 1997); see also statements of Henry Hildebrand, Chapter 13 Trustee, at Meeting of
National Bankruptcy Review Commission Consumer Bankruptcy Working Group, Apr. 17-18, 1997
(informal survey of Chapter 13 trustees in 5 cities indicated that of their Chapter 13 cases filed in
1996, percentage of debtors that had filed previous case between January 1, 1990 and December 31,
1996 ranged from 1% to almost 23%).
Return to text
729 See, e.g., Letter from Hon. Polly S. Higdon, Bankruptcy Judge D. Or., regarding consumer
bankruptcy (Sept. 25, 1996) (attaching listing of multiple filings in District of Oregon and analyses
by bankruptcy judges of their repeat filers); Susan L. DeJarnatt, Empirical Study-Chapter 13 Repeat
Filings; Preliminary Analysis, Draft (September 11, 1997).
Return to text
730 See letter from Hon. Polly S. Higdon, Bankruptcy Judge D. Or., (April 23, 1997) (citing this
as primary reason for repeat filings in numbers of cases); Letter from Hon. Geraldine Mund, Chief
Bankruptcy Judge C.D. Cal. (June 23, 1997) (commenting that any time bar should not be triggered
by dismissal of case due to debtor error, such as failure to appear at section 341 examination or failure
to file schedules or statement of affairs so as not to prejudice pro se filers who do not "get it right"
the first time).
Return to text
731 See, e.g., Letter from Mallory Duncan, Vice President & General Counsel, National Retail
Federation to National Bankruptcy Review Commission regarding Chapter 13 plan success rates, 2
(June 16, 1997) (some Chapter 13 plans fail because debtors withdraw after partial completion, since
courts in most jurisdictions allow debtors to pay secured debt arrearage early in plan).
Return to text
732 See Report of the United States Bankruptcy Court, Central District of California Ad Hoc
Committee on Unlawful Detainer and Bankruptcy Mills (Jan. 1997) (reporting that when court formed
ad hoc committee, over 16% of consumer cases had been filed primarily to stop eviction, which was
down to 1% in 1996); Memorandum from Eric Friedman, Assistant Vice President and Bankruptcy
Manager, Countrywide Home Loans regarding barring multifilers (Apr. 14, 1997) (one primary
reason for repeat filings is to delay foreclosure); Kirk Loggins, Author Loses Court Battle;
Foreclosure Imminent, The Tennessean (Jan. 4, 1996) (author and husband engaging in "serial and
tag team" bankruptcy filings to delay foreclosure for four years).
Return to text
733 The Central District of California, commonly cited as the primary locus of the serial filing
problem, created an Ad Hoc Committee on Unlawful Detainer and Bankruptcy Mills, comprised of
several judges, the U. S. Trustee, attorneys from the U.S. Attorney's Office and other private
organizations representing various landlord interests. Since 1991, this committee has monitored the
situation. Using a "complex web of law and actions to control the abuse," the committee's data
indicates that filings initiated primarily to stop eviction in this district have decreased from 16.9% in
1991 to 1% in 1996.
Return to text
734 The Supreme Court has confirmed that this two-case approach is viable. Johnson v. Home
State Bank, 501 U.S. 78, 87 (1991) ("Congress did not intend categorically to foreclose the benefits
of chapter 13 reorganization to a debtor who has previously filed for chapter 7 relief"). Reportedly,
the technique is becoming "increasingly common." In re Turner, Civ. No. 96-16189, 1997 WL 72056
at *5 (B.A.P. 2d Cir. February 27, 1997). Although some courts review the cases comprising a
Chapter 20 collectively and with a high level of scrutiny to determine whether the debtor is
comporting with statutory requirements and is acting in good faith, see, e.g., In re Limbaugh, 194
B.R. 488, 491 (Bankr. D. Or. 1996) (comparing Chapter 20 cases with separate classification in
Chapter 13), there is little question that Chapter 20 cases are permitted under the Code as it stands.
Return to text
735 See 11 U.S.C. § 109 (1994).
Return to text
736 See Summary of Consumer Bankruptcy Framework Proposals (Draft, June 10, 1997) adopted
June 20, 1997, reconsidered August 12, 1997. Although the proposal stated that the two-year bar
would run from the closure of a Chapter 13 case, this trigger was problematic. See Letter from Hon.
Geraldine Mund, Chief Judge, U.S. Bankruptcy Court, Central District of California (June 23, 1997)
(noting that closing is artificial time that is dependent on workload of clerk's office as well as
documents received from Chapter 7 trustee).
Return to text
737 See Letter from Dean S. Cooper, Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corp. (Freddie Mac) to
National Bankruptcy Review Commission (Mar. 25, 1997) (endorsing two-year filing bar);
Memorandum from Eric Friedman, Assistant Vice President and Bankruptcy Manager, Countrywide
Home Loans regarding barring multifilers (Apr. 14, 1997) (providing statistics showing that
multifilers rarely complete their plans the second or third filing, and thus end result is still filing);
Letter from Jennifer Johnson, Bankruptcy Supervisor, FT Mortgage Companies, to Susan Jensen-Conklin, regarding proposed changes to Chapter 7 and Chapter 13 (Apr. 17, 1997) (strongly
supporting multi-year ban on refilings); Letter from Michelle D. Viner, Bankruptcy Supervisor,
Assistant Secretary, Norwest Mortgage, Inc., Mes Moines, IA to National Bankruptcy Review
Commission, regarding discussion paper draft Mar. 3, 1997 (Apr. 25, 1997) (recounting serial filing
problems). See also letter from Francis M. Allegra, Deputy Associate Attorney General, U.S.
Department of Justice, to National Bankruptcy Review Commission 2 (June 18, 1997) (noting that
serial filings are problematic in many jurisdictions and that refiling bar "appears to balance fairly the
interests of debtors and creditors, and would curtail abuses of the bankruptcy process by repeat
filings").
Return to text
738 Stating his opposition to the amendment, Senator Howell Heflin stated that the National
Bankruptcy Review Commission would be the proper forum to consider the issue of repetitive filings.
140 CONG. REC. S4521-01 (daily ed. Apr. 20, 1994).
Return to text
739 Senator Supports Limiting Chapter 13 Eligibility, 3 CONSUMER BANKR. NEWS 5 (June 3, 1994).
Return to text
740 140 CONG. REC. S4521-01 (daily ed. Apr. 20, 1994). Senator Heflin expressed that the
inflexible provision would work hardship on honest debtors who may have legitimate reasons for their
prior noncompletion and refiling. Id. Senator Grassley characterized the amendment as "using a
cannon to go after a fly" and was concerned that the amendment would discourage the use of Chapter
13 repayment plans. Id. at S4532.
Return to text
741 This amendment was rejected by a vote of 60 to 34. 140 CONG. REC. D407-01 (daily ed. Apr. 20, 1994).
Return to text
742 See Letter from Hon. Polly S. Higdon, Bankruptcy Judge D. Or. (Apr. 23, 1997)
(concluding that a uniform and restrictive remedy is not well-suited to variety of causes of repeat
filings and advocating an alternative approach to provide more equity to honest debtors while
protecting interests of creditors); Letter from Hon. Joe Lee, Bankruptcy Judge E.D. Kentucky, to
Commissioner M. Caldwell Butler (July 18, 1997) (recommending more moderate but effective
restrictions on successive filings).
Return to text
743 Some courts issue orders that essentially accomplish this result. In re McKissie, 103 B.R. 189
(Bankr. N.D. Ill. 1989) (enjoined from filing another Chapter 13 for one year); In re Doss, 133 B.R.
108 (Bankr. ND. Ohio 1991) (enjoined from filing for one year). However, the Commission has
recommended that prospective orders that affect rights and obligations in bankruptcy cases not yet
filed not be recognized. It is appropriate for this remedy to be provided statutorily.
Return to text
744 Letter from Hon. Joe Lee, Bankruptcy Judge E.D. Kentucky, to Commissioner M. Caldwell Butler (July 18, 1997) (delineating effects of this recommendation); see also Letter from Hon. Robert
W. Alberts, United States Bankruptcy Judge C.D. Cal., to the National Bankruptcy Review
Commission (May 7, 1997) (endorsing withholding of automatic stay on subsequent filings).
Return to text
745 See Memorandum from Michael S. Polk, Polk Scheer & Prober, regarding repeat filings (Apr.
15, 1997) (describing sophisticated strategies to avoid foreclosure, and recommending statutory
authority for courts to providein rem relief); see also Michael S. Polk, Stop the Attack of the Equity
Skimmers, MORTGAGE BANKING 82 (Feb. 1988) (advising lenders how to protect equity position by
guarding against techniques that use bankruptcy to postpone foreclosure).
Return to text
746 Another variation apparently is for transferors to fill out several deeds in blank, each
transferring a partial interest, and then to hire homeless people to be the transferee and to file for
bankruptcy. See Letter from Geraldine Mund, Chief Bankruptcy Judge C.D. Cal. to National
Bankruptcy Review Commission regarding In rem orders (June 23, 1997) (recommending additional
amendment toin rem proposal).
Return to text
747 See, e.g, Letter from Haydon Stanley, Georgia Apartment Association ( June 3, 1997) (reporting that some residents are utilizing loopholes in Bankruptcy Code to circumvent eviction
process); Letter from L.A. Buddy Patrick, Atlanta Apartment Association (June 3, 1997), forwarded
by Hon. Newt Gingrich, Speaker, U.S. House of Representatives (August 13, 1997).
Return to text
748 "Unwary creditors may suffer losses at the hands of debtors who abuse the multiple filing opportunities provided by Chapter 13." In re Nash, 765 F.2d 1410, 1414 (9th Cir. 1985).
Return to text
749 At the April 1997 meeting in Seattle, Washington, Jill Sturdevant of Bank of America stated that the problem, while most prevalent in the Los Angeles area, is not limited to California. Indeed,
in In re Cherokee New York Inves., 1995 WL 548182 (Bankr. E.D.N.Y. 1995) (unreported decision),
Judge Marvin Holland addresses the problem.
Return to text
750 See, In re Snow, 201 B.R. 968 (Bankr. C.D. Cal. 1996) (impressing equitable servitude on
property); In re Fernandez, 1997 WL 523997 (Bankr. C.D. Cal. 1997) (unreported decision) ("based
on the history of multiple filings and the bad faith of our Debtor and those associated with him, the
court concludes that our Debtor is not entitled in this fifth related bankruptcy case to enjoy again the
benefits of the automatic stay and that here, the bank was not required to obtain yet another order for
relief from the stay before foreclosing on the Sea View property . The Court concludes that the in
rem relief from stay order entered in the prior Amador bankruptcy case is enforceable against the
Debtor, even though the Debtor in this case was not afforded written notice of the bank's motion for
relief from stay in the Amador case"); In re Amador, No. 97-14711ES (Bankr. C.D. Cal. Apr. 14,
1997) (unpublished order) (ordering that any relief from stay granted movant will be of full force and
effect in this case and in case filed by any other entity claiming interest in subject property within 180
days of entry of order).
Return to text
751 See Letter from Hon. Geraldine Mund, Chief Bankruptcy Judge C.D. Cal. to the National
Bankruptcy Review Commission regarding consumer bankruptcy issues" (Nov. 25, 1996) ("There
has never been a clear decision about whether the court has the power to give orders that are
prospective in granting relief from stay and/or that are in rem . . . no one really knows if these are
valid and enforceable orders"); Memorandum from Michael S. Polk, Polk Scheer & Prober, to the
National Bankruptcy Review Commission, regarding repeat filings (Apr. 15, 1997) (judges do not
believe they have authority without specific statutory foundation). See, e.g., In re Cherokee N.Y.
Invs., 1995 WL 548182 (Bankr. E.D.N.Y. 1995) (unreported decision).
Return to text
752 See Chapter 2 of the Report.
Return to text
753 See Memorandum from Clarine Nardi Riddle, Nat'l Multi Housing Council, Nat'l Apart.
Ass'n (Oct. 8 & 9, 1996) (attaching preferred language for recommendation excepting from automatic
stay any action for eviction, summary process, or unlawful detainer proceedings involving residential
real property, and providing that possession of residence by tenant under rental agreement shall not
be property of estate).
Return to text
754 Section 362(b)(10) excepts from the automatic stay a lessor's acts to obtain possession of
nonresidential real property when a lease has terminated by the expiration of the stated term of the
lease, and has been interpreted to apply whether the lease ended by time expiration or on account of
a default. In re Neville, 188 B.R. 14 (Bankr. E.D.N.Y. 1990).
Return to text
755 See S. REP. NO. 98-65, at 68 (1983), Erickson v. Polk, 921 F.2d 200, 201 (8th Cir. 1990).
Return to text
756 Tenants have initiated litigation in the bankruptcy court to attempt to revive their interests
even when there has been conclusive state court litigation, which most bankruptcy courts would agree
should have preclusive effect on the status of the lease. See In re Issa Corp., 142 B.R. 75 (Bankr.
S.D.N.Y. 1992) (citations omitted). A debtor might bring a contempt action relating to the debtor's
eviction even if a state court already found that the debtor received adequate notice, see In re Neville,
118 B.R. at 17, or a contempt action in the context of a dispute over whether the lease actually
expired; see In re Hejco, Inc., 87 B.R. 80 (Bankr. D. Neb. 1988). In addition, some landlords have
had to litigate whether the debtor retained an equitable interest in the property or whether the
bankruptcy court should exercise equitable powers to "revive" the lease. See In re Erie Builders
Concrete Co., 98 B.R. 737 (Bankr. W.D. Pa. 1989) (finding absence of exigent circumstances that
might warrant court's use of section 105 powers to extend debtor's right to possession, after district
court already terminated lease extension); Neville, 118 B.R. at 18. The process of obtaining the
property sometimes is protracted further by motions for reconsideration or to file additional
memoranda, see id., or by motions seeking stays pending appeal. See In re Urbanco, Inc., 122 B.R.
513 (Bankr. W.D. Mich. 1991) (denying stay pending appeal); Issa, 142 B.R. at 78 (granting debtor's
unopposed request for stay pending appeal of court's denial of motion to assume expired lease,
although noting that debtor's argument was of "dubious validity"); In re Cybernetic Services, Inc.,
94 B.R. 951 (Bankr. W.D. Mich. 1989) (denying stay pending appeal). Although lessors tend to
prevail in these actions involving expired leases, they obtain relief only after the delay attendant to
litigation and the decision-making process. It therefore is not surprising that some landlords seek
bankruptcy court permission in advance, notwithstanding the fact that a landlord meeting the
standards of section 362(b)(10) is not required to seek bankruptcy court permission to vacate or lift
the stay. See, e.g., Urbanco, 122 B.R. at 520 (noting superfluity of order modifying stay to permit
lessor to proceed in state court); In re The Depot, Inc., Civ. No. 91-33819, 1992 WL 101790 (Bankr.
N.D. Ohio Jan. 22, 1992) (granting relief from stay, rejecting contention that continued possession
of property was necessary for successful reorganization); In re Jarman, 118 B.R. 380 (Bankr. D.S.C.
1989) (granting relief, noting that automatic stay was inapplicable in any event because "there was
nothing for the automatic stay to protect" on date of bankruptcy filing); In re Damianopoulus, 93 B.R.
3 (Bankr. N.D.N.Y. 1988); In re Hampton, 78 B.R. 357, 358 (Bankr. N.D. Ga. 1987) (lease expired
on own terms on day before bankruptcy filing, thus, court lifted stay to permit lessor to obtain
possession).
Return to text
757 According to the Seventh Circuit, termination of a residential lease on account of default may
constitute expiration: "[f]ederal bankruptcy law draws no meaningful distinction between 'expired'
and 'terminated' residential leases . . . Instead, the federal law allowing 'unexpired' leases to be
assumed calls for a determination whether a lease has ended under state law." Robinson v. Chicago
Housing Authority, 54 F.3d 316, 319 (7th Cir. 1995). A lease has been terminated for these purposes
if 1) the landlord has taken all necessary procedural steps to repossess the premises; and 2) the debtor
has no further legal recourse to revive the lease. Robinson, 54 F.3d at 321. Applying Illinois law,
the Robinson court found that its test was clearly satisfied, and a lease had expired, upon entry of a
judgment for possession. However, in cases where no judgments for possession were on the docket
prior to the bankruptcy filings, courts applying Robinson and Illinois law have reached conflicting
conclusions on what satisfies the Seventh Circuit's termination test. Interpreting the second prong
of the test, one court found that even if a tenant has a colorable claim to challenge a landlord's attempt
to terminate, termination has occurred once "a tenant has defaulted in payment of rent, the landlord
has given whatever demand for rent is required, and the tenant has failed to pay the demanded rent
within the required time." In re Finkley, 203 B.R. 95, 100 (Bankr. N.D. Ill. 1996). To satisfy the first
prong of the test, merely filing an action for possession would suffice. Id. at 102. By contrast, another
court in the Northern District of Illinois literally interpreted the Robinson test, considered due
process implications, and reached the conclusion that in the absence of a judgment, a lease had not
"expired" because the Illinois forcible entry and detainer process was not completed and the debtor
retained statutory defenses and additional recourse to contest the proceedings. In re Brown, No. 95
B 16825, 1995 WL 904913 at *3 (Bankr. N.D. Ill. Dec. 19, 1995). Other courts have
attempted to delineate when a residential lease has "expired" or been "terminated" under applicable
state laws, separate from the question of whether an individual has an equitable right in the leasehold.
See In re Windmill Farms, 841 F.2d 1467 (9th Cir. 1988) (lease is terminated no later than when
landlord files unlawful detainer proceeding); In re Mims, 195 B.R. 472 (Bankr. W.D. Okla. 1996)
(under Oklahoma law, lease did not expire for section 365 purposes until writ of assistance was
executed and served on debtor); In re Talley, 69 B.R. 219, 225 (Bankr. M.D. Tenn. 1986) (lease
unexpired until execution of writ of possession under Tennessee law); In re Morgan, 181 B.R. 579,
584 (Bankr. N.D. Ala. 1994) (interpreting Alabama law, writ of restitution necessary for expiration
of lease, thus lease remained assumable although landlord sought to "terminate" it pre-bankruptcy);
In re Smith, 105 B.R. 50 (Bankr. C.D. Cal. 1989) (lessee has no property interest in lease and stay
does not apply if landlord has obtained judgment for possession); In re Collier, 163 B.R. 118 (Bankr.
S.D. Ohio, 1993) (lease not assumable under Ohio law after docketing of landlord's state court
forcible entry and detainer action); In re Schewe, 94 B.R. 938 (Bankr. W.D. Mich. 1989) (although
stay applies to lease, under Michigan law, tenancy at will in mobile home provides "cause" for lifting
automatic stay). In addition, the anti-forfeiture provisions in some states might preclude a finding of
expiration or termination, even when a landlord has obtained a judgment. See, e.g., Ross v.
Metropolitan Dade County, 142 B.R. 1013, 1015 (S.D. Fla., 1992) (lease did not expire for section
365 purposes under Florida law even if judgment of possession has been entered), aff'd, 987 F.2d 774
(11th Cir. 1993); In re Sudler, 71 B.R. 780, 785 (Bankr. E.D. Pa. 1987) (under Pennsylvania anti-forfeiture provisions, tenancy not terminated until housing authority obtained actual delivery of real
property).
Return to text
758 See Report of the United States Bankruptcy Court Central District of California Ad Hoc
Committee on Unlawful Detainer and Bankruptcy Mills (January 1997) (rate dropping from over 16%
in 1991 to 1% in 1996).
Return to text
759 See 11 U.S.C. § 1328(a)(2), (a)(3) (1994). Student Loan Default Prevention Initiative Act of
1990, Pub. L. No. 101-508, § 3007(b), 104 Stat. 1388; Criminal Victims Protection Act, Pub. L. No.
101-581 §§2(b), 104 Stat. 28 and (3) (overruling Supreme Court's decision in Pennsylvania Dept.
of Pub. Welfare v. Davenport, 110 S. Ct. 2126 (1990) which held that criminal restitution obligations
are dischargeable if debtor completes Chapter 13 plan).
Return to text
760 Even a debtor who receives a "hardship discharge" without completing a plan does not get the
benefit of the superdischarge.
Return to text
761 See Tax Advisory Committee Final Report (August 1997) (committee divided on three
proposals relating to superdischarge); Letter from Heidi Heitcamp, Attorney General for North
Dakota and Chair, Bankruptcy and Taxation Working Group, Nat'l Association of Attorneys General
(Apr. 4, 1997) (superdischarge enables ill intentioned debtors to discharge debts incurred fraudulently
with very little repayment commitment); Patricia L. Barsalou, Removing Chapter 13 Superdischarge
Provision for Tax Debts, 4 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 494 (1996); see also "American Bankruptcy
Institute Roundtable- Consumer Bankruptcy Issues Facing the Commission,: American Bankruptcy
Institute Journal (July/Aug. 1996) (illustrating strongly disparate views on superdischarge).
Return to text
762 See Memorandum from Commissioner Hon. Edith H. Jones regarding discharge and
dischargeability in consumer bankruptcy, (May 20, 1997) (seeing no reason to maintain availability
of superdischarge because it "is rarely useful, and when it is, it tends to shield conduct of a sort that
society has seen fit to condemn").
Return to text
763 See Letter from Francis M. Allegra, Deputy Associate Attorney General, U.S. Department of
Justice 6 (June 18, 1997) (unsupportive of fresh start through superdischarge for those who have
committed misconduct).
Return to text
764 11 U.S.C. § 109(e) (1994) (individual is eligible for Chapter 13 if she has regular income and
owes $250,000 or less in unsecured debt and $750,000 or less in secured debt).
Return to text
765 See Memorandum from Commissioner James I. Shepard (Apr. 7, 1997) (bankruptcy should
not become a tax haven); Patricia L. Barsalou, Removing Chapter 13 Superdischarge Provision for
Tax Debts, 4 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 494 (1996).
Return to text
766 See, e.g, Hon. Marilyn Morgan, Bankruptcy Judge, N.D. Cal., comments for the National
Bankruptcy Review Commission (May 14, 1997) (noting that "bankruptcy judges sometimes joke that
in our day jobs we're tax collectors" and suggesting that it is better to collect part of the taxes
than none of the taxes); ABI Consumer Bankruptcy Reform Forum Summary and Report on Options
at 7 (undated) ("Chapter 13 has permitted the recovery of substantial tax revenues at low collection
cost").
Return to text
767 Even if debtors do pay the principal on nondischargeable debts in full during the course of a
plan, some courts have held that any interest still accruing during the course of the three to five years
is not discharged. See discussion on student loan dischargeability earlier in this report.
Return to text
768 See, e.g., Testimony of National Association of Consumer Bankruptcy Attorneys to the
National Bankruptcy Review Commission, Proposals for Improving the Consumer Provisions of the
Bankruptcy Code, (May 14, 1997) (recommending that there should be enhanced superdischarge for
plans that go two years longer than required).
Return to text
769 The Commission's Proposal to eliminate the exception to discharge for educational loans,
which also were excepted from Chapter 13 discharge since 1990, also would have an effect on the
Chapter 13 discharge.
Return to text
770 Fair Credit Reporting Act § 605(d), 15 U.S.C. § 1681 et seq. (1996); see generally National
Consumer Law Center, Fair Credit Reporting Act Changes Affect Bankruptcy, NCLC Reports;
Bankruptcy and Foreclosures Edition 11 (1996).
Return to text
771 See David M. Howe, How Can Debtors be Motivated to Complete 100% Chapter 13 Plans,
CH. 13 TRUSTEE MESSENGER 1 (February 1996) ( acknowledging that there is little recognizable
benefit for debtor to struggle to make full repayment if credit reporting agencies continue to report
full repayment in Chapter 13 as straight bankruptcy discharge).
Return to text
772 See Karen Gross, Introducing a Debtor Education Program into the U.S. Bankruptcy System:
A Roadmap for Change (July 7, 1997); Jean Braucher, Counseling Consumer Debtors To Make their
Own Informed Choices- A Question of Professional Responsibility, 5 AM. BANKR. INST. L. REV. 165,
188 (1997) ("there are many indications that chapter 13 does not bring better credit access, and that
chapter 7 may even be preferred by creditors"); Comments of Tom Phillips, Georgia State University,
(electronic transmission) (August 9, 1997) (recommending restructuring of consumer credit
evaluation and reporting procedures, since under current law, "debtor's credit is equally affected
(ruined) regardless of which bankruptcy option is exercised"); Letter from Ramona Winkelbauer, to
National Bankruptcy Review Commission, regarding recommendation for bankruptcy reform (Sept.
4, 1997) (recommending that credit reporting agencies be required to report type of bankruptcy case
filed by individuals and date of filing. "By 'tarring' all bankruptcy filers with a single label,
responsible consumers have difficulties recovering from their need to file. This practice is unfair to
those individuals that attempt to reorganize their debts by filing a Chapter 13").
Return to text
773 Karen Gross, Introducing a Debtor Education Program into the U.S. Bankruptcy System: A
Roadmap for Change, Submitted to the National Bankruptcy Review Commission (July 7, 1997).
Return to text
774 See Comments of Tom Phillips, Georgia State University, (electronic transmission) (August
9, 1997) ("I would suspect that many debtors, given the opportunity to rebuild their credit, or even
have their credit rating less adversely affected, through reasonable repayment plans to their creditors,
would opt for a mutually agreed-upon repayment plan rather than total default.").
Return to text
775 15 U.S.C. § 1681 et seq (1996).
Return to text
776 ABI Consumer Bankruptcy Reform Forum Summary and Options (Undated).
Return to text
777 See, e.g., Frank M. Pees, Chapter 13 and Chapter 12 Trustee, Southern District of Ohio,
Eastern Division, The Affect [sic.] and Scope of Credit Rehabilitation Following the Successful
Completion of a Chapter 13 Plan 2 (Dec. 17, 1996) (describing credit re-establishment program);
Office of Ray Hendren, Standing Chapter 13 Trustee, Western District of Texas, Austin and Waco
Division, Credit Rehabilitation Program Life After Chapter 13: What Do I Do Now? (undated); Tom
Powers and Tim Truman, Standing Chapter 13 Trustees, Northern District of Texas, Dallas-Fort
Worth Division, The Dallas-Fort Worth Debtor Education/Credit Rehabilitation Handbook (3d ed.
rev. 1996) (citing Frank Pees and Al Olsen, Chapter 13 trustee in San Antonio, as first to have credit
liaisons).
Return to text
778 Pees, at 5; The Thirteen Connection (Creditor/Debtor Attorney Issue) (Spring 1996) (listing nearly 70 credit grantor participants for Dallas- Fort Worth program).
Return to text
779 Powers and Truman at 14-15.
Return to text
780 The amounts listed generally do not include "wildcard" exemptions that may be applicable to real property. The acreage limitations imposed in some states also have not been listed. Although
reasonable efforts have been expended to ensure the accuracy of this information, consultation with
selected state statutes and several secondary sources sometimes provided ambiguous or conflicting
accounts of the amounts of the exemptions.
Return to text
|