DISSENT TO THE COMMISSION'S RECOMMENDATIONS: PARTNER AS DEBTOR
By HONORABLE EDITH H. JONES
The Bankruptcy Code does not satisfactorily
address the issues arising from partnership or limited
liability company (LLC) bankruptcies. Thus, I applaud
the Commission's efforts to lend stability and sense to
this currently muddled area of bankruptcy law. I applaud
those proposals that would treat members or managers of
LLCs consistently with partners in partnerships and that
would exclude partnership, LLC and analogous
relationships from 11 U.S.C. § 365; partnerships and LLCs
are not properly governed by the "executory contract"
provisions of the Code. Unfortunately, I think other
changes adopted by the Commission will adversely affect
the development of partnership law outside the bankruptcy
area and will impose higher transactional costs on the
vast majority of partnerships that will not go bankrupt.
I must respectfully dissent from those other proposals.
My criticisms of the partnership proposals are
friendly ones. The proposals clearly attempt to
accommodate state law and pre-existing partnership
agreements to a great degree; my only objection is that
they ought to go further in that direction. I have been
persuaded by the response of Professor Ribstein (2773) to
these proposals, and my comments largely parallel those
he and others in the transactional field have expressed.
Before proceeding further, it is useful to
summarize the alternate proposals that I believe Congress
ought to consider for adapting bankruptcy law to members
of partnerships, LLCs and analogous firms. First, 11
U.S.C. § 365 (executory contracts) should not apply to
such entities. Second, the law should clarify the
enforceability of partnership and analogous agreements
regarding rights of bankrupt partners. Third, neither 11
U.S.C. § 362 (the automatic stay) nor any other Code
provision should interfere with the effectuation of these
agreements. Fourth, a bankrupt member's rights in a
partnership or analogous firm and whether these rights
are property of the estate under section 541 and subject
to control and disposition under section 363 should be
governed by state law.
Several general principles inform these
recommendations.(2774) First, partnerships and LLCs are
important, extremely flexible investment vehicles and
reflect detailed and costly planning. Ribstein Letter,
at 2. Mandatory bankruptcy rules, added to the federal,
state and tax laws that appertain, increase the
complexity of what is already a daunting drafting task.
Id.
Second, "state competition and experimentation
are more likely to produce rules that efficiently balance
partner and creditor interests than imposing a single
federal law." Id. The uniformity of federal law, stated
as a justification for displacing state laws, is in
doubt, because the Commission's proposals -- particularly
regarding the definition of "ipso facto" clauses -- are
just as likely to produce divergent caselaw as have the
precedents applying section 365 to partner bankruptcies.
Professor Ribstein adds that where uniformity is
necessary to reduce creditors' costs, his research
demonstrates that "states move in this direction on their
own." Id.
Third, "state partnership law is better able
than federal law to take into account rapidly changing
circumstances affecting business organizations." Id.
Tax law provides a particular source of uncertainty.
Bankruptcy law should free states and firms to deal with
regulatory changes.
Fourth, as Professor Ribstein notes, "by
trumping state law rights, bankruptcy law may give
partners and creditors perverse incentives to initiate
costly and unnecessary bankruptcy proceedings." Id. If
bankruptcy law provides parties a potential recovery or
right that does not exist under the partnership agreement
or state law, opportunities exist for forum-shopping.
For instance, a partner might initiate a personal
bankruptcy in order to utilize the no-ipso facto rule
advanced by this Commission's proposal. Id. A partner
with a cash-flow problem but whose assets exceed
liabilities could obtain a benefit for himself while
imposing bankruptcy costs on creditors and non-debtor
partners. Id. As another example, an undersecured
creditor might be able to use a bankruptcy proceeding to
avoid a low buyout provision under the debtor's
partnership agreement, if federal bankruptcy law creates
a more favorable buyout formula. Id.
Fifth, the experience of lawyers in
transactional practices suggests that creditors who deal
with partners as borrowers generally realize the risks
they are taking in relying on the partnership interest
for repayment and can adjust to those risks legally and
economically. If lenders are unable to protect
themselves adequately, by requesting more security or
higher interest rates or shorter payout periods, that is
their oversight and not a general problem with which
bankruptcy should be concerned. Insofar as the
Commission's proposals imply that a partner's creditors
need special protection, the assumption is counter-intuitive. Moreover, what bankruptcy law appears to give
with one hand -- in attempting to increase the value of
a partner's interest for the benefit of creditors -- it
probably takes away with the other hand by fostering
litigation and bankruptcy's high transactional costs.
Finally, to the extent that these proposals
might allow debtors to remain as active partners/LLCs
contrary to state law or ipso facto clauses, and would
authorize the forced substitution of a new partner/LLC
member in a partnership/LLC, they might create value for
the debtor's estate where none would have existed under
state law. Bankruptcy law should not, however, be in the
business of creating value, but only in fairly
distributing the debtor's property among creditors
according to standards determined by extrinsic law.
Butner v. United States, 440 U.S. 48 (1979). I recognize
that the proposals attempt to interfere with state and
contract rights as little as possible, but the provisions
to which I refer will inevitably be over-utilized because
of their potential for creating value that parties to the
proceeding would not otherwise enjoy.
With this background, I have particular
objections to three specific parts of the partnership
bankruptcy proposals.
A. Ipso Facto Clauses
Although ipso facto clauses that have the
effect of terminating or modifying parties' rights to a
contract based on insolvency, financial condition,
commencement of a bankruptcy case or appointment of a
trustee are not ordinarily enforceable in bankruptcy, I
believe a distinction must be drawn between their
enforceability in contractual relationships and in
partnership or LLC agreements. Invalidating ipso facto
clauses in contracts is essentially different from
interfering with the complete business organization.
Contractual ipso facto clauses may be viewed as bilateral
solutions to damage and performance questions that would
otherwise arise during a bankruptcy. Partnership and LLC
agreements, however, are the constitutional documents for
business organizations. Breach of such agreements does
not have a simple bilateral effect, as would a contract
breach. Rather, the effects of breach ripple throughout
the organization. Further, the business organization
documents, or state law by default, represent a carefully
bargained-for multilateral assessment of the rights and
interests of the affected members of the organization.
Ipso facto clauses founded on bankruptcy or insolvency
provide a cleancut way to identify a threat to the
organization and supply its solution by, for instance,
automatically expelling a bankrupt partner.
The Commission's proposals would result in a
world without ipso facto clauses to protect
partnerships/LLCs in the event of a member's bankruptcy.
In such a world, considerably more adroit legal drafting
would be required to solve the problems that arise on
bankruptcy of a partner or LLC member without referring
to the member's bankruptcy or financial condition.
Moreover, it is not clear that creditors are better off
in such a world, for their optimal remedy is probably to
share in the expelled member's buyout from the firm.
Consider an example. The general partner of a
real estate partnership falls seriously in arrears in his
financial contributions. On filing bankruptcy, however,
with the ipso facto clause invalidated, and no other
clause permitting expulsion, that partner would continue
to make decisions concerning the running of the
partnership.(2775) But is it not intuitively obvious that the
bankrupt partner will be participating in the firm with
much different goals in mind than those of other
partners? The partner is in no position to contribute
credit to the organization (in the form of vicarious
liability); the partner may not fully bear his load of
the firm's debt during the bankruptcy; and the partner's
perspective on future earnings, which may go to
creditors, may well diverge from the firm's interests.
See Ribstein, Expelling Bankrupt Partners. The essential
community of interest among the organization's members
has been severed by the bankruptcy.
Professor Ribstein's letter makes additional
points. He advises that members should be allowed to
provide for automatic expulsion of a bankrupt partner and
to fix a price in the agreement that is triggered by
bankruptcy. Ribstein Letter, at 3. First, ipso facto
provisions are efficient state law rules, which the
Commission's proposal invalidates. Id. State law
"recognizes that non-debtor partners and LLC members
often need to sever their relationship with bankrupt
partners because of their different incentives and
interest in the firm following bankruptcy". Id.
Professor Ribstein continues:
Accordingly, state law provides
by default for the expulsion of
bankrupt partners and LLC members
and for payment for their interests
in the firm. State law also permits
enforcement of partnership and LLC
agreement provisions for payment of
less than the market value of the
bankrupt partner's interest. This
accommodates the partners' cash-flow
and other problems that could result
when a partner's bankruptcy triggers
a sudden buyout obligation.
Second, the [Commission]
proposal undoubtedly will give rise
to litigation over whether a buyout
price or expulsion is an "ipso
facto" provision. For example, is a
buyout price enforceable if it
applies only to partner bankruptcy
and partner divorce? This hardly
"fosters predictability" as the
Proposal asserts.
Third, as discussed in my
working paper, [Expelling Bankrupt
Partners] there is no compelling
bankruptcy interest at stake. There
is clearly no problem with expulsion
of bankrupt partners, and indeed
this may be in creditors' interests
if it is the best way to ensure a
buyout of the bankrupt partner.
Even if the bankruptcy estate is
denied some value by reason of the
"ipso facto" provision, this is no
different from the effect of secured
creditors' priority. Such state law
rights have been upheld for good
reasons and . . . there are equally
good reasons to apply state
partnership law and partnership
agreements in bankruptcy. [One may]
recognize the potential concern that
partners may create "spendthrift
trusts" for themselves by making
investments in partnerships that
creditors cannot reach. But because
this tactic also hurts solvent
partners, it is mainly a problem in
the sort of eve-of-bankruptcy
context that is covered by
fraudulent conveyance law. Thus,
per se invalidation of such
provisions is unnecessary.
B. Management Rights
Both Professor Ribstein and Richard Levin(2776)
forcefully criticize the novel proposal to include a
partner's management rights as part of the "property of
the estate," contrary to state law. Creditors are
entitled under state partnership law only to the debtor's
"economic" interests in the firm. Only a few rogue
bankruptcy cases have held otherwise. Including
management rights as part of the debtor's estate raises
a Pandora's box of complex questions concerning
valuation, transfer, the debtor's rights and a trustee's
role that obscure rather than clarify creditors'
entitlements. I agree with these experts' conclusion
that the debtor's management rights should not become
part of the debtor's bankruptcy estate. If they do not,
then there is no need to provide, as the proposal
attempts to do, for exercise of management rights by a
trustee. Mr. Levin draws a helpful analogy to illuminate
the proposal's lack of conceptual coherence:
In the corporate context, the
trustee cannot take over the
debtor's role as an officer or
director of a corporation just by
virtue of becoming trustee of the
debtor's estate. To be sure, the
trustee as a shareholder may elect a
new board and take over the
corporation that way, but that is
different from stepping into the
shoes of an individual for
employment or management purposes.
Mr. Levin further points out:
A disputing partner should not be
able to use the bankruptcy laws to
prevent his ouster from the
partnership/LLC, anymore than a
corporate officer should be able to
retain his position by filing a
bankruptcy petition.
If ipso facto clauses are permitted, in most
cases, the partnership/LLC agreements, or by default
state law, would permit expulsion and buying out the
bankrupt partner. No management rights would remain to
be dickered about.
C. Transferability and Valuation of a
Partnership or LLC Interest
Given the history of partnership law and the
reality of the unique relationships that exist among
partners, it is incredible to contemplate the
Commission's proposal, the first of its kind in my
understanding, that would allow a partnership interest to
be sold and the purchaser forced upon unwilling non-debtor partners. To enunciate this recommendation, it
seems to me, is to refute it. The Commission proposal
would, however, change the law and under certain
circumstances permit the court to order either the sale
of the bankrupt partner's interest and admission of the
buyer into the firm or the buyout of the bankrupt partner
or member.
Professor Ribstein summarizes the reasons for
questioning this proposal:
Under state partnership law, a
partner's creditor is entitled to a
charging order and, under some
statutes and case law, to judicial
foreclosure of this charging order
that would make the creditor
essentially the assignee of the
partner's interest. However, even
foreclosure would not necessarily
entitle the creditor to a buyout,
and as assignees creditors may not
be able to dissolve the firm or
otherwise obtain the value of the
partner's or member's interest.
These rules involve a complex
adjustment of the rights of
creditors and non-debtor partners
worked out on a statute-by-statute
and case-by-case basis under state
law. For the general policy reasons
discussed above, it is inappropriate
to supplant this state law
development with a federal
provision. Moreover, special
federal rules would give partners'
creditors a perverse incentive to
put partners into bankruptcy so that
they can realize more on the
partners' interests than they could
under state law. This would trigger
substantial bankruptcy costs merely
to satisfy the selfish objectives of
a few creditors.
Ribstein Letter, at 4.
The Commission's proposal on forced buyout of
a partner interest, though somewhat less troubling than
forced substitution, attempts to defer to state law and
partnership/LLC agreements. The proposal allows
enforcement of (non-ipso facto) partnership/LLC governing
documents that restrict transfers of membership, but
"only if" the partnership/LLC pays the "buyout price";
the "buyout price" is defined as the highest non-bankruptcy-related value provided in the documents, or if
there is none, a "fair price". The forced buyout
provision permits the court to fix reasonable payment
terms, balancing the needs of the debtor's estate and the
firm. It is not the buyout I object to so much as the
court's authority to fix a price for it.
The perceived evil that this proposal seeks to
avert is sub-market buyout valuations that would unfairly
penalize creditors of a partner/LLC debtor. Professor
Ribstein questions the utility of this proposal:
The problem of sub-market-value
buyouts is not normally a serious
one, however. Partnership buyout
provisions typically are triggered
by any partner dissociation,
including those resulting other than
from bankruptcy. If the partners
were willing to deny market value to
themselves on retirement or to their
estates on death without knowing in
advance whether they would be the
surviving or remaining partners then
the price presumably reflects both
the costs and benefits of sub-market-value buyout even if a
particular buyout ultimately is
triggered by bankruptcy. Creditors'
interests do not justify
invalidating such a clause.
Ribstein, Expelling Bankrupt Partners, at 14.
The Commission's "fair price" provision ignores
the ability of a partner's creditors to ascertain the
partnership's buyout terms and adjust their credit
decisions accordingly. The provision also affords
redundant creditor protection. If the partner's buyout
provision has been set at zero or unrealistically low to
hinder, defraud or delay creditors, fraudulent conveyance
and other laws already address the problem.
Finally, the Commission's proposal invites
distracting litigation over whether a buyout provision
was "on account of" bankruptcy if the provision also
covers other events, such as partner divorce. Clever
drafters could make the interpretation of this provision
difficult. Enforcing state law and thereby the
partnership/LLC agreements offers on balance a clear,
efficient, fair and inexpensive means to distribute the
debtor/partner's interest among the creditors.
CONCLUSION
Before Congress enacts these provisions, which
change the rights that partners have among themselves and
with regard to creditors of a bankrupt partner, it should
look closely at the consequences for partnership/LLC law
development generally and consider whether an additional
layer of regulation of these extremely inventive types of
business organizations is really needed. The bankruptcy
tail should not wag the formidable investment dog that
has been created by modern partnership/LLC law.
Notes:
2773 Professor Larry E. Ribstein, GMU Foundation Professor of law, George
Mason University, Co-author of Allen R. Bromberg and Larry E. Ribstein, Bromberg
& Ribstein on Partnership (1988); Ribstein and Keatinge, Limited Liability
Companies. Return to text
2774 These comments draw heavily upon Professor Ribstein's Letter to Stephen
H. Case concerning NBRC Partnership Proposals, May 27, 1997 ("Ribstein Letter");
my conversations with transactional lawyers; and Professor Ribstein's article, The
Federalization of Partnership Breakup: Expelling Bankrupt Partners, George Mason
University School of Law, Law and Economics Working Paper No. 97-01 (May 19,
1997) [hereinafter Expelling Bankrupt Partners]. Return to text
2775 A previous version of these proposals limited the application of the automatic
stay to certain kinds of intra-partnership actions. The final version of the proposals
does not do so, and I infer that the partners would be prevented from expelling this
partner without first gaining approval of the bankruptcy court. Return to text
2776 Mr. Levin is now a partner at Skadden, Arps and was a principal legislative aide when the 1978 Bankruptcy Code was enacted. His view of the Commission's
partnership proposal appears in a letter to Ms. Liz Holland, Commission staff
member, June 13, 1997. Return to text
|